Mises Daily

Martin Van Buren: The American Gladstone

[This article is excerpted from Chapter 6 of Reassessing the Presidency: The Rise of the Executive State and the Decline of Freedom, edited by John V. Denson.]

 

President Martin Van Buren does not usually receive high marks from historians. Born of humble Dutch ancestry in December 1782 in the small upstate New York village of Kinderhook, Van Buren gained admittance to the bar in 1803 without benefit of higher education. Building upon a successful, country legal practice, he became one of the Empire State's most influential and prominent politicians, during the very period when the state was surging ahead as the country's most populous and wealthy. After election to the United States Senate in 1821, this consummate backroom strategist helped mastermind a reemergence of ideologically distinct political organizations out of the corrupt and faction-ridden interlude of single-party rule — euphemistically labeled "The Era of Good Feelings" — that had followed the War of 1812. A new Democratic Party resuscitated the old Jeffersonian alliance between planters of the South and plain Republicans of the North, united behind the charismatic hero of the West, General Andrew Jackson.

Jackson was elected to the White House in 1828, and Van Buren succeeded to the presidency as Old Hickory's heir-apparent on March 4, 1837. This triumphant fulfillment of a lustrous career would prove short-lived, however. The eighth US president was soundly defeated for reelection in 1840, initiating a new series of single-term chief executives. Four years later, the Democracy rejected its venerable architect as presidential nominee, and Van Buren's 1848 candidacy as standard bearer for the Free Soilers, an antislavery third party, failed to carry a single state. The elderly New Yorker survived long enough to witness the outbreak of Civil War but passed away in July 1862, at the age of seventy-nine.

Van Buren was a lawyer-president who represented a new breed of professional politician. His opponents denounced him during his life for subtle intrigue, scheming pragmatism, and indecisive "non-commitalism." These charges were reflected in such popular nicknames as the Little Magician, the Red Fox of Kinderhook, and the American Talleyrand. The ideologically compatible but personally acerbic John Randolph of Roanoke once observed that "he rowed to his objective with muffled oars," faulting Van Buren as "an adroit, dapper, little managing man," who "can't inspire respect."1 Van Buren's demeanor reinforced these impressions. Appearing shorter than his five feet and six inches, he was stout and balding by the time of his inauguration, his formerly red sideburns now gray and framing a large head with a prominent brow and calculating blue eyes. Always fashionably dressed, charmingly witty and imperturbably amiable, Van Buren never let political differences master his emotions or cloud his social relations. He was not a daring, original intellect in the mold of John C. Calhoun of South Carolina, and his ability to draw out the views of others often masked his pious devotion to orthodox Jeffersonianism.

Even sympathetic historians tend to slight Van Buren's term in office as the third Jackson administration. Arthur M. Schlesinger, Jr., concludes that, while president, "Van Buren was weak in the very respect in which he might have been expected to excel — as a politician." Except during the last year in office, his management was "negligent and maladroit" and showed very little "executive energy."2 On the other hand, modern advocates of decentralization and states' rights are often more taken with Van Buren's better-known rival, Calhoun, and his doctrine of nullification. Van Buren admittedly would not go to the lengths of a John Randolph in sacrificing political success for ideological purity. Yet the New Yorker's career overall displayed far more consistency in opposing government power at all levels than the many twists and turns of the swaggering opportunist from South Carolina. Van Buren was also better attuned to Old Republican 3

I - Foreign Policy

Greatness must be measured against some standard. Let us begin our examination with foreign policy, the area where a president's individual traits probably can make the most difference in history's trajectory. Conventional historians tend to have a nationalist bias that makes them appreciate a strong executive who lastingly contributes to the growth of central authority. They thus have a particular weakness for wartime presidents. Unless the commander-in-chief turns out to be utterly inept, war allows him to show off forceful, dynamic leadership. In a 1961 collection of scholarly articles on America's Ten Greatest Presidents, for instance, half the subjects were presidents who had dragged the country into war. And when the collection was revised ten years later to make it America's Eleven Greatest Presidents, the additional chapter was on Harry Truman, a president whose reign spread over two hot wars plus a cold war.4

In contrast, presidents merit recognition for keeping the United States out of war, and Van Buren has the unique distinction of keeping the United States out of two: one with Mexico and another with Britain. Van Buren's deep commitment to peace and neutrality was evident even before he assumed the highest office. He was instrumental, as Jackson's first secretary of state, in negotiating the opening of direct trade with the British West Indies, a long-standing American goal that the previous administration of John Quincy Adams had completely botched. In the midst of Old Hickory's second term, while Van Buren was serving as vice president, the president's hot temper almost provoked conflict with France over spoliation claims arising out of depredations on American commerce during the Napoleonic Wars. The vice president, fortunately, helped moderate Jackson's belligerence and bring the dispute to an amicable settlement.

Jackson's closing policies, however, handed the president-elect another potential conflict. The hero of New Orleans had looked on with pleasure as American settlers in the Mexican province of Texas declared independence in 1836 and staged a successful revolt. Popular expectations ran high on both sides of the southwest border that the fledgling Texas Republic would soon join the United States. But Mexico refused to recognize the new nation, and the Texas constitution sanctioned slavery, setting off a hue and cry among American abolitionists about the "Slave Powers" latest expansion into new territory. Any annexation by the United States threatened both a foreign war and domestic political controversy between Southerners and Northerners. Although the Little Magician helped to delay formal US recognition of Texas independence until after safely winning the 1836 presidential election, the retiring Jackson menacingly pressed American claims against the Mexican government for monetary damages.

But the new president, unlike his predecessor, was not eager for war in the southwest. On top of his sincere desire for friendly relations with all foreign powers, Van Buren correctly foresaw that territorial expansion might split Democratic ranks. He therefore deftly rebuffed Texas overtures, and Secretary of State John Forsyth of Georgia announced on August 25, 1837, formal rejection of the offer of annexation. Over the next two years, Van Buren's diplomatic skill and patience got the Mexican government to accept arbitration of US claims by a commission made up of two members from each country and one designated by the King of Prussia.

The eighth president's hope for peace endured well after he left office. Machinations on the part of President John Tyler of Virginia and none other than John C. Calhoun subsequently catapulted Texas annexation into the midst of the 1844 presidential campaign. Van Buren was then frontrunner for the Democratic nomination. Yet he issued a public statement favoring annexation only if it could be accomplished without upsetting US relations with Mexico, despite his full knowledge that this qualification would cost him politically. "We have a character among the nations of the earth to maintain," Van Buren avowed. While "the lust of power, with fraud and violence in the train, has led other and differently constituted governments to aggression and conquest, our movements in these respects have always been regulated by reason and justice."5 An increasing number of Southern Democrats turned away from the New Yorker, including Jackson himself — dying but still influential. The Little Magician held support from a majority of delegates as the party's convention opened in Baltimore, but the convention rules required a two-thirds vote to nominate. After eight deadlocked ballots, the delegates settled on the first dark-horse candidate in American history: James Knox Polk of Tennessee, an ardent expansionist. Polk would win a slim victory at the presidential polls and then conduct the very war that Van Buren had tried so hard to prevent.6

President Van Buren also could have had a war over Canada. The United States had twice mounted military expeditions to conquer its Northern neighbor, first during the American Revolution and again during the War of 1812. At other times, annexation was under consideration, sometimes to the point of encouraging insurgencies similar to those that helped swallow up Florida and Texas. Van Buren was in office less than a year when rebellions broke out in both Lower and Upper Canada. Americans lent support to the rebel "patriots" with recruits and provisions, and although Canadian authorities easily dispersed any organized resistance, border incidents kept anti-British feelings at fever pitch, especially in the president's home state. A raiding party of Canadian militia in December 1837 violated US territory near Buffalo, New York, in order to burn a small steamship, the Caroline, that was transporting supplies to the rebels, killing one US citizen. In retaliation, a group of Americans boarded and burned the Canadian steamer, Sir Robert Peel, on the St. Lawrence in May 1838.

Any one of these incidents might have led to a declaration of war, had Washington and London wanted a fight. The president responded to the crisis by issuing two strong proclamations of neutrality, by calling out the militias of New York and Vermont to enforce the proclamations, and by sending General Winfield Scott on a mediatory mission. Scott was a member of the opposition Whig Party but a loyal subordinate. A giant man, he traveled up and down the eight hundred-mile frontier in full dress uniform using little more than his personal influence to calm inflamed passions.

No sooner had the one crisis subsided than another, even more dangerous one flared up. The boundary between Maine and New Brunswick since 1783 had left twelve thousand square miles in dispute. Canadian lumberjacks took up timber operations in the disputed region along the Aroostook River during the winter of 1838 — 1839. When the Canadians refused an order of the Maine legislature to leave, the state militia marched to the river and nervously faced New Brunswick troops in a confrontation that became known as the Aroostook War. Democratic Governor John Fairfield of Maine warned Van Buren that "should you go against us upon this occasion — or not espouse our cause with warmth and earnestness and with a true American feeling, God only knows what the result will be politically."7 Realizing that a single diplomatic misstep could cause tensions in either country to erupt into bloodshed, the president emphatically supported Maine's claim but warned Governor Fairfield that the federal government would not tolerate the state unilaterally drawing it into open hostilities. As Congress authorized fifty thousand volunteers, extended militia drafts from three to six months, and appropriated $10 million for war, Van Buren again dispatched General Scott to the trouble spot. Together they negotiated a truce in which both sides withdrew their forces in March 1839.8

None of the outstanding issues between the United States and Canada had been resolved fully when the New Yorker stepped down in 1841. The Maine boundary was still unsettled, the United States was still demanding an apology for the Caroline incident, and the British government was vigorously protesting New York state's murder trial of a Canadian deputy sheriff, Alexander McLeod, for his participation in the Caroline raid. Nonetheless, the Little Magician's astute and unruffled diplomacy had preserved the peace, leaving final settlements to a future administration. In this case, President Tyler followed Van Buren's lead by negotiating the Webster-Ashburton Treaty of 1842 with Britain, bringing all major questions to a mutually satisfactory conclusion. What makes President Van Buren's peaceable determination all the more exemplary was its political cost. During his reelection bid in 1840, Whig victories in the normally Democratic northern tier of New York counties cost him that state, and it was the only time the Whig Party ever carried Maine and Michigan in a presidential race. Indeed, a few of the Red Fox's closest political advisers had privately urged him to start a foreign war in order to distract public attention from the administration's domestic difficulties.9

II - Domestic Policy

With respect to domestic policies, Martin Van Buren would have been quite pleased to let his time in office become a placid addendum to the tumultuous eight years of President Jackson. One historian, Major L. Wilson, has characterized Van Buren's inaugural address as "essentially a charter for inaction."10 It contained nothing more innovative than calls for "strict adherence to the letter and spirit of the Constitution" and for "friendship of all nations as the condition most compatible with our welfare and the principles of our Government."11 But fate ironically intervened. Only two months after the inauguration, a major financial panic engulfed the country's eight hundred banks, forcing all but six to cease redeeming their bank notes and deposits for specie (gold or silver coins).

The preceding Jackson presidency had slowly and painfully brought ideological definition to the Democratic Party. Van Buren, for instance, had persuaded Old Hickory to veto appropriations for the Maysville Road, eventually making opposition to nationally funded internal improvements part of the Democratic canon. Although the Little Magician once had supported protective tariffs in an effort to enlist Northern votes for Jackson's election, whereas the General himself had been evasive, the nullification crisis put the Democracy solidly behind tariff reduction. But the controversy that came to eclipse all others in drawing new party lines was the "Bank War." The hardening disposition of President Jackson and his western advisers against a nationally chartered bank escalated from Jackson's resounding veto of the bill to recharter the Second Bank of the United States in 1832 into a crusade to destroy what they called "the Monster." The Treasury gradually transferred its sizeable deposits from the Second Bank into an assorted group of state-chartered banks, and then in July 1836, Old Hickory issued a "Specie Circular," requiring payment for public land in only gold or silver, rather than bank notes.

By the time of Van Buren's elevation to the White House, hostility to any new national bank unified all Democrats. Within this consensus, however, two factions had arisen. The less numerous but more radical group, epitomized by Senator Thomas Hart Benton of Missouri and the Locofoco contingent of New York City Democrats, advocated a complete "divorce" of the national government from dealings with all banks in an effort to promote hard money. The majority, led by Senators Nathaniel P. Tallmadge of New York and William C. Rives of Virginia, who would soon style themselves "conservatives," believed that the "credit system" promoted economic growth and wanted to maintain the intimate relationship between the government and state-chartered deposit banks. They had gone so far as to join with the opposition in Congress to repeal Jackson's Specie Circular, only to have the general pocket veto the bill.

Van Buren at first tried to reconcile the two factions, as befit his personality and past record. On the one hand, when serving in the New York legislature, he had voted against all bank charters, save one for war-ravaged Buffalo, and as early as 1817, he had advocated throwing banking open to unrestricted competition, a radical proposal two decades ahead of its time. On the other hand, as the Empire State's governor in 1829, he had sponsored creation of the Safety Fund, a system of government-mandated bank note insurance. The panic of 1837, however, pushed the Little Magician, along with many other wavering members of his party, unequivocally into the radical camp. If the national government did not sever its relationship with the suspended state banks — with their unredeemable, depreciating paper currency — then it would be in the same position as at the close of the War of 1812, when financial chaos had provided the impetus for chartering the Second Bank.

Holding firm against mounting pressure to revoke the Specie Circular, the president called an emergency session of Congress to convene at the beginning of September 1837. His message to this first special legislative session since the presidency of James Madison was a bold and acute program to meet the depression with government retrenchment. "All communities are apt to look to government for too much," warned Van Buren. "Even in our own country, where its powers and duties are so strictly limited, we are prone to do so, especially at periods of sudden embarrassment and distress."12 To yield to this temptation, however, would be a mistake, because "[a]ll former attempts on the part of the Government" to "assume the management of domestic or foreign exchange" had in his opinion "proved injurious." What was needed was a "system founded on private interest, enterprise, and competition, without the aid of legislative grants or regulations by law,"13 one that embodied the Jeffersonian maxim "that the less government interferes with private pursuits the better for the general prosperity." The president therefore refrained "from suggesting to Congress any specific plan for regulating the exchanges of the country, relieving mercantile embarrassments, or interfering with the ordinary operation of foreign or domestic commerce," because "their adoption would not promote the real and permanent welfare of those they might be designed to aid."14

Daniel Webster; Whig senator from Massachusetts, denounced the president's message for "leaving the people to shift for themselves."15 The lone exception to Van Buren's rejection of government activism was a proposal for a new bankruptcy law that would allow the national government to shut down any bank that too long suspended specie payments. The Twenty-fifth Congress refused even to consider this measure. But it quickly enacted the president's suggestion of granting importers a six-month moratorium on payment of customhouse bonds. What makes this tax relief significant is the fact that tariffs were the national government's only source of revenue at the time, outside of the sale of public lands. Of still greater import was the legislature's willingness to go along with Van Buren's insistence on halting distribution of federal money to the state governments. Senator Henry Clay of Kentucky and his neo-Hamiltonian Whigs had saddled the previous administration with this nineteenth-century version of modern revenue sharing after the national debt had been paid off for the first and only time in American history. General Jackson, "with a repugnance of feeling and a recoil of judgment" according to "Old Bullion" Benton, had signed off on the distribution of the surplus because John C. Calhoun had incorporated it into a bill regulating the Treasury's dealings with the deposit banks.16 But after the panic, federal revenues declined, and there was no longer any surplus revenue to hand out. Along with ending distribution, Congress accepted Van Buren's preference to finance the reappearing national debt with $10 million worth of short-term Treasury notes rather than long-term loans.

But the centerpiece of the Little Magician's special message was his courageous call for a total separation of bank and state through an Independent Treasury. The Independent Treasury was an idea that could assume several forms and accommodate differing views on currency and banking, but its most fundamental requirement was that the government hold all monetary balances in the form of specie, rather than bank notes or deposits. Either existing Treasury officials or newly established subtreasuries could serve this function. Some versions restricted to specie all payments received by the government as well, whereas others let the Treasury accept notes from specie — paying banks so long as they were speedily redeemed or paid back out. Such ultra-bullionists as Senator Benton hoped that the Independent Treasury, by eliminating government support for bank notes, would ultimately drive them out of circulation and return the entire economy to an exclusive hard-money currency. Supporters of unregulated banking, among them Dr. John Brockenbrough, president of the Bank of Virginia, realized that the national government's finances were too small relative to the economy to effect this result and hoped in contrast that a divorce would be good for the state banks. Still others, including Secretary of the Treasury Levi Woodbury of New Hampshire, wanted to supplement the Independent Treasury with some federal regulation of banking, such as restrictions on bank notes of small denominations. And some proponents went so far as Senator James Buchanan of Pennsylvania in favoring a government-issued paper money, anticipating the Greenbacks and gold certificates of the Civil War.17

Administration spokesman Silas Wright of New York introduced into the Senate an Independent Treasury bill that simply assigned the keeping of funds to existing officials and was silent on how payments could be made. Calhoun then startled members of both parties with another one of his sudden but inept political reversals. Abandoning his Whig allies, he announced his support for the administration initiative. Calhoun, however; wanted to modify it by turning Treasury notes into a permanent government currency and by phasing in over four years a requirement that the Treasury Department accept only specie or its own notes. Since a specie-requirement was already implicit in Van Buren's message, the administration had to accept this amendment. Although the widespread bank suspensions had tended to discredit state banks as government depositories, Calhoun's amendment now stiffened the opposition of Conservative Democrats to the divorce bill. Nor did it help when the Calhounites portrayed divorce as a sectional issue that would free the South from Northern capital, linking the question to the interminable debates over abolitionist petitions that were preoccupying Congress at the time. The amended divorce bill passed the Senate by two votes, but it was tabled in the House. In later sessions, when the administration reluctantly dropped the specie requirement in order to pick up Conservative votes, the Nullifier turned against the measure.

Yet de facto the Treasury was already independent. The Currency Resolution of 1816 forbade the government to receive bank notes not redeemable in specie, another law forbade paying them out, and the Deposit — Distribution Act of 1836 did not permit the Treasury to hold funds in any suspended bank. The president ordered federal officials to comply with these regulations as far as possible, which meant that, with the exception of the balance in deposits tied up at the time of the panic, the Treasury was only receiving, holding, and paying out either specie or Treasury notes. Once the banks resumed specie payments in May 1838, most of them still could not qualify as depositories under the Deposit Act's restrictions because during the suspension they had issued small-denomination notes. Frustrated at Congressional obstinacy, Van Buren considered emulating Old Hickory's high-handedness by establishing an Independent Treasury through executive order; but such a violation of legislative prerogatives suited neither his temperament nor his philosophy.

The depression meanwhile politically hurt the administration. Elections in the fall of 1837 turned against the Democrats in many states, particularly New York, where the Whigs gained an overwhelming majority in the state legislature's lower house by winning a stunning sixty-seven seats. The "New York tornado," as the shocked Van Buren called it, was followed a year later by the capture of the Empire State's governorship by Whig candidate William H. Seward. The combination of Whigs and Conservative Democrats in the Twenty-fifth Congress continued to block enactment of the Independent Treasury throughout much of the eighth president's term. Despite favorable votes in the Senate, the House of Representatives voted against a divorce bill during the first regular session in 1837 — 1838 and refused to vote on it at all during the second regular session of 1838 — 1839. The legislators were far more interested in a scandal that the Treasury had just uncovered in the New York City Customs House. The collector; Samuel Swartwout, had allegedly embezzled over the previous eight years the astonishing sum of $1.23 million and then fled to Europe. Even though Swartwout was an old Jackson appointee to whom Van Buren had vigorously objected, and moreover a former Calhoun favorite who was now a Whig, the Democratic administration was put on the defensive.18

Van Buren nonetheless scored some unheralded successes. After bank resumption in 1838, administration stalwarts in Congress defanged a new Whig-Conservative effort to revoke the Specie Circular by converting it into an act that merely made it unlawful to treat receipts from public land differently than other revenue. The secretary of the Treasury thereby gained the discretionary authority to accept only specie for all payments or also bank notes for all payments. The divorce bills furthermore had shifted the terms of the debate and forestalled any proposal for a new national bank. The Little Magician had instead maneuvered Clay and the Whigs into a political defense of the same "pet" bank system they had so vociferously denounced during Jackson's presidency. He also had achieved an uneasy reconciliation with Calhoun and a few other states'-rights Southerners, whom the autocratic Jackson had driven out of the Democratic camp. Finally, the Conservative insurgency, if not smoothed over, was at least contained. Failing to gain dominance within Democratic councils, Conservatives faced the alternatives of either following their prominent leaders Tallmadge and Rives into the Whig Party or of again submitting to their own party's discipline. One indication of increasing Conservative isolation was the editorial shift of the New York Democracy's official newspaper, the Albany Argus. It went from lukewarm about the Independent Treasury to a ringing announcement in June 1838 that "[w]e believe the time has emphatically come for the separation of bank and state."19

Van Buren's refusal to abandon the goal of divorce ultimately paid off as the political tide turned in late 1839. When a second suspension of specie payments spread to half the country's banks that October, it seemed to verify the administration's suspicion of state depositories. The Democrats managed to retain control of both houses of the Twenty-sixth Congress, which met for its first session in December. The president's annual message renewed the call for an Independent Treasury reinforced with new arguments. The latest suspension was more obviously the result of international factors than had been the panic of 1837, which had coincided with all the confusing policy changes of Jackson's Bank War. Van Buren now argued that only divorce could free the US economy from "tins chain of dependence" on credit flows of "the money power in Great Britain." The message also dampened the laissez-faire tone of Van Buren's earlier message to the special session and accentuated its hard-money radicalism with a willingness to consider "additional legislation, or, if that be inadequate … such further constitutional grants or restrictions" that might check "excessive note issues."20

Fortunately the legislators voted down both a bankruptcy bill, similar to the one the president had suggested in his earlier message, and Senator Buchanan's proposed constitutional amendment authorizing Congress to ban bank notes of less than $20. The tireless Senator Wright again introduced a divorce bill in the Senate, this version including both special subtreasuries to hold government funds and Calhoun's specie requirement for receiving payments. The bill sailed through the Senate at the end of January 1840, but the House, experiencing more than its usual disorder and delay over disputed seats and choice of speaker; did not pass the measure until June. Van Buren waited until July 4, 1840, to sign the law, symbolically confirming the words of The Washington Globe, the administration's mouthpiece, which nearly three years earlier had hailed the Independent Treasury as "the second declaration of independence."21

III - Retrenchment in Crisis

The Independent Treasury ushered in an era of financial deregulation at the national level. Although repealed in 1841, after the Whigs captured the White House, they could not agree among themselves about an alternative. President William Henry Harrison died after less than a month in office and was succeeded by Vice President John Tyler; an apostate Democrat. Tyler vetoed Henry Clay's two bank bills, leaving the government's deposit system unregulated by law. Use of state banks remained at the secretary of the treasury's discretion until President James Knox Polk, a doctrinaire Jacksonian who enthusiastically embraced the fiscal heritage of Martin Van Buren, secured reenactment of what he preferred to call a Constitutional Treasury in August 1846. The act of 1846 was identical in substance to that of 1841 and determined the country's financial regime until the outbreak of the Civil War.

Laissez-faire may not have been the intent of all those who supported the divorce of bank and government. And perhaps a more efficient way to attain that goal would have been to freely charter competitors with the Second Bank, with equal powers of interstate branching, rather than abolishing that institution altogether. Nonetheless, laissez-faire was the Independent Treasury's primary consequence. There was no nationally chartered bank, the Treasury for the most part avoided dealing with the many state-chartered banks, and the only legally recognized money was gold and silver coins. Because the economy's currency consisted solely of bank notes redeemable in specie on demand, private competition regulated the circulation of paper money.

Although traditional historians have subjected this era of relatively unregulated banking to trumped-up charges of financial instability, many economists are coming to agree that it was probably the best monetary system the United States has ever had. The alleged excesses of the fraudulent, insolvent, or highly speculative "wildcat" banks were highly exaggerated. Total losses that bank note holders suffered from 1836 to 1861 in all the states that enacted free-banking laws would not equal the losses for one year from an inflation of 2 percent, if superimposed onto the economy of 1860. Moreover; most of these losses resulted from too much regulation, not too little. Lingering at the state level were prohibitions on branch banking, mandates for minimum specie reserves, restrictions on the issue of small-denomination bank notes, and requirements that banks purchase state bonds, which at this time were among the most dubious investments. The banks were also still vulnerable to international flows of specie. No monetary system is perfect. But by any objective comparison, this one was relatively stable and crisis-free.22

Those historians who dismiss the Independent Treasury as constraining the government "to accept payments and to make them in an antiquated medium" more "suitable for the War of the Roses" have never adequately explained the relative quiescence of monetary debates during its operation.23 The First and Second US Banks had divided political parties since the adoption of the Constitution. The Civil War's national banking system and Greenbacks subsequently induced fresh convulsions over currency questions. If the Independent Treasury was in fact so obviously deficient, why did it provoke no similar political outcry? Moreover; its reenactment coincided with heavy expenditures for Polk's war against Mexico, yet that military effort caused the economy less financial dislocation than any previous American war. During the nation's next financial panic in 1857, the Treasury was effectively insulated from the bank suspension. There is also no evidence that the Independent Treasury hobbled the country's economic growth.24

The domestic policies of the Van Buren presidency, however; did more than bequeath a superior financial regime. They also thwarted all attempts to use economic depression as an excuse for expanding government's role. Prior to the panic of 1837, state governments — in an uncanny parallel to the recent currency crises in east Asia and Russia — had borrowed more than $100 million from abroad to finance lavish and wasteful internal improvements. Most states experienced financial stringency as a result of the panic, and many became desperate. By 1844, $60 million worth of state bonds were in default. Three states — Arkansas, Michigan, and Mississippi — as well as the Florida territory repudiated their debts outright.25 Henry Clay saw this as a heaven-sent opportunity to revive his distribution scheme under a new pretext. The Whigs of the Twenty-sixth Congress hence advocated that the national government bail out the states by assuming their debts. Clay's party also had its own proposal for a bankruptcy law — not like Van Buren's that would close banks involuntarily, but rather one that would allow individual debtors voluntarily to escape their obligations.

Democrats under the Little Magician's leadership not only blocked these initiatives but pushed government involvement in the opposite direction. Although total national expenditures suddenly spiked to $37.2 million in 1837, overall they declined through Van Buren's four years, from $30.9 million in 1836 to $24.3 million in 1840. That represents a 21 percent fall in nominal terms, no more than half as much if you adjust for price changes, but somewhere in between if you also adjust for population growth or the economy's size.26 Many of these spending cuts came in the realm of internal improvements, especially for rivers and harbors, where Van Buren was far more stringent than Old Hickory had been.27 As for revenue, tariff rates were already falling as a result of programmed reductions worked out during the compromise over nullification. So the president threw his weight behind two measures that would bring the allocation of public land into closer alignment with the homestead principle: preemption, giving settlers who cultivated the land first option to buy; and graduation, reducing the price on unsold land. Graduation failed to pass, but Congress renewed earlier preemption acts twice during Van Buren's term.28 At the end of the four years, with significant cuts in both national spending and revenue, the depression-generated debt was holding near $5 million.29

Closer examination of the economy's fluctuations reveals the enormous benefits of this retrenchment. The two banking crises that dominated the Van Buren administration had similar causes but different outcomes. In both cases, the proximate cause was a decline in foreign inflows of specie precipitated when the Bank of England raised its discount rate. The panic of 1837, however; was a sharp and short correction that followed right on the heels of two years of price inflation at an annual rate approaching 15 percent. After wholesale prices fell back nearly 20 percent over a year; and output less than 5 percent, the economy seemed to recover. The suspension of 1839, in contrast, hit fewer banks but foreshadowed a protracted deflation. The country's total money stock — specie, banknotes, and bank deposits — declined by one-third during the next four years, and prices plummeted 42 percent.30

Many economists have been struck by the comparison between this second episode, the deflation of 1839 — 1843, and the subsequent Great Depression of 1929 — 1933. Qualifying as the two most massive monetary contractions in American history, they were of identical magnitude and extended over the same length of time. But there the similarities end. During the Great Depression, as unemployment peaked at 25 percent of the labor force in 1933, US production of goods and services collapsed by 30 percent. During the earlier nineteenth-century contraction, investment fell, but amazingly the economy's total output did not. Quite the opposite; it actually rose between 6 percent and 16 percent. This was nearly a full-employment deflation. Nor are economists at any loss to account for this widely disparate performance. The American economy of the 1930s was characterized by prices, especially wages, that were rigid downward, whereas in the 1840s, prices could fall fast and far enough to quickly restore market equilibrium.31

But why were prices and wages so much more flexible when Van Buren was at the helm? The fact that the Great Depression, America's deepest and longest economic downturn, was also the first to be met with a comprehensive program of federal intervention offers some hint. Intervention commenced, furthermore, not with the well-known New Deal of President Franklin D. Roosevelt, who did not enter office until early 1933 when the economy was almost at rock bottom, but with his predecessor; Herbert C. Hoover. This progressive Republican's long tenure during the 1920s as secretary of commerce, promoting trade associations, product standardization, and business cartels, prepared him to meet the stock-market crash of October 1929 with a vigorous effort to stop any fall of prices. Starting with a series of White House conferences jawboning business leaders into "voluntarily" holding up wage rates, Hoover pressed with mixed results for further cartelization in agriculture, in the cotton textile industry, in commercial aviation, and in the energy industries — coal, oil, and electricity. He also signed into law in 1932 the largest peacetime tax increase in US history, and practically closed the borders to foreign trade with the Smoot-Hawley Tariff of 1930, the highest in American history in an effort to hold up prices internationally. Roosevelt's National Recovery Administration and Agricultural Adjustment Administration simply made this concerted campaign for price supports more formal.32 Prices did indeed still drop by 31 percent from 1929 to 1933, but not nearly as much as during the deflation of the 1830s and 1840s. Although government policies may not explain fully the price rigidity of the 1930s, they explain a lot.

The Little Magician, of course, was not single-handedly responsible for preventing the earlier deflation from becoming another Great Depression. His heroic resistance to the expansion of central power received vital aid from the Democratic coalition that he had helped to forge. And given that total federal spending started at less than 2 percent of GDP in the mid 1830s, as compared with nearly twice that in the 1920s, Clay's misguided recovery measures would probably not have been as economically devastating as those of Hoover and Roosevelt. Once Van Buren's term ended, a few of Clay's measures were implemented briefly. Congressional Whigs were able to secure President Tyler's assent to their voluntary bankruptcy bill, to a watered-down distribution of the proceeds from land sales to the states, and to a tariff hike justified as a way to eliminate depression deficits. But the distribution was abruptly ended in 1842, after only a year; in order to secure enough legislative votes for the tariff increase, whereas the Whigs themselves were embarrassed into repealing the bankruptcy act in 1843 after thirty thousand fortune-seekers had used its provisions to get out of more than $400 million worth of debt.33 The deflation had just about run its course, anyway, and by 1846 the new Polk administration had brought the tariff back down. The refusal to bail out defaulting state governments produced a widening ripple of salutary effects, not the least of which was making more difficult any future squandering of state money on public works and government-owned railroads. The Red Fox of Kinderhook thus had held the pass at the crucial time, when doing so was politically unpopular, against powerful mercantile, financial, and other special interests clamoring for national assistance. The depression of 1837, more than any other factor; brought about his overwhelming trouncing in the presidential election of 1840 at the hands of General Harrison, hero of the battle of Tippecanoe.

IV - Illiberal Lapses

No politician, especially one successful enough to be elected to the United States's highest office, can be perfect. Martin Van Buren's most morally egregious and fiscally exorbitant compromises with government coercion stemmed from his faithful adherence to Andrew Jackson's ruthless program of Indian removal. Most of the tribes of the Southwest had already gone to Oklahoma, but an assortment of Northwest tribes still awaited deportation beyond the Missouri River. More troublesome, seventeen thousand Cherokee had legally delayed eviction from their homes in North Carolina, Georgia, Tennessee, and Alabama, whereas approximately four thousand Seminoles mingled with more than one thousand blacks, many of them escaped slaves, were putting up effective military resistance in Florida. Although General Winfield Scott did his best to ensure that Cherokee removal was peaceful and humane, bad weather and inadequate appropriations turned the journey into a "Trail of Tears," in which hundreds perished before the process was completed in early 1839. The second Seminole war, having erupted in 1835 prior to Van Buren's inauguration, degenerated into a vicious and unrelenting counterinsurgency struggle that was still raging as he left office. President Tyler finally ended what had become the US Army's most costly and lengthy Indian war with a proclamation in 1842 that permitted three hundred surviving Seminoles to remain in Florida on reservations, essentially the same terms that Van Buren had rejected in 1838. The war and other removals occasioned a one-half increase in the regular army's authorized size — from around eight thousand to more than twelve thousand soldiers — and a new string of forts. The most that can be said in the Little Magician's behalf is that these burdensome expenses make his success at rolling back federal expenditures all the more remarkable.34

Because the Seminoles harbored fugitive slaves, the Florida war was intimately intertwined with concessions that Van Buren made to slaveholders. During his first presidential bid, the Calhounite press had tried to cripple the New Yorker's candidacy in the South by branding him an abolitionist. Van Buren countered with an announcement that he was "the inflexible and uncompromising opponent of any attempt on the part of Congress to abolish slavery in the District of Columbia, against the wishes of the slaveholding states."35 He also went along with various "Gag Rules" on receiving abolitionist petitions that Congress implemented between 1836 and 1844, and during the 1840 election promised to veto any antislavery restrictions Congress might place on Florida's admission to the Union. His accommodation with the peculiar institution had greatest practical impact in the case of the Amistad, a Spanish schooner that had fallen into the custody of a US revenue cutter in 1839, after the slaves on board had successfully mutinied. The president stood ready to hand the blacks over to Spanish authorities, despite their having been illegally kidnapped from Africa. But the case became tied up in US courts, and after the administration appealed, the Supreme Court in March 1841 freed the Africans.36

Although the Little Magician's Faustian bargain to hold together the sectional wings of a national party dedicated to frugal government was more pronounced during his presidency than either before or after, its extent should not be exaggerated. Nearly twenty years earlier Van Buren, serving in the New York legislature, had endorsed the prohibition of slavery in Missouri, as he would later support the Wilmot Proviso, barring the extension of slavery into the territories acquired from Mexico. Not only was the eighth president quite capable of disappointing slaveholder hopes for Texas annexation, but he never appeased Southerners to the lengths that a James Buchanan would endorse or a John C. Calhoun would demand. The president refused to overturn the conviction of a navy lieutenant court-martialed for excessive flogging, in spite of Southern complaints that the prosecution had relied on testimony of two black seamen.37 The New Yorker's vice-presidential running mate in both 1836 and 1840 was a Southerner, Colonel Richard M. Johnson of Kentucky, yet hardly one who made his fellow slave-holders comfortable. Johnson had violated the color line by openly living with a black mistress and acknowledging their two daughters. Such limits on Van Buren's ability to placate Southerners were reflected by the stiff presidential opposition he faced in 1836 in the South, a region that had gone solidly for Old Hickory. The Little Magician did even worse in the South in 1840 running against Harrison, an Ohioan who was Virginia-born.38

The Van Buren administration's readiness to return the Amistad mutineers was also motivated in part by diplomatic considerations. The objective of friendly relations with foreign powers was responsible for another of the president's lapses in 1837. To supplement efforts to calm tensions during the Canadian rebellions, he asked Congress for a new neutrality law. The existing act of 1818 was mainly maritime, and Van Buren wanted the power to prevent private citizens from organizing raids on foreign soil. Congress was in this instance more sensitive to civil liberties, so it declined to permit the use of military force against groups merely organizing and planning such an expedition. Instead, under a new law that would expire two years after its passage in 1838, civil authorities could seize arms, ammunition, vehicles, and vessels attempting to cross the border.39

Two years later. Van Buren carelessly passed along to Congress a report from his secretary of War; Joel R. Poinsett. Poinsett (for whom the poinsettia was named) was a staunch Unionist from South Carolina, more nationalistic than his chief executive. The administration's frequent diplomatic and military tribulations inspired the secretary to request a militia reorganization similar to what had been suggested by nearly every president since George Washington. Under the plan, the regular army each year would call out and rigorously drill from the state militia rolls an active force of one hundred thousand men, who would then be available for rapid mobilization. Once the Whigs got wind of this scheme for universal military training, they set off an uproar. Many states were already undermining the basis for such a reorganization by replacing their compulsory militias with voluntary systems. The Little Magician, who had not previously read the plan, promptly disavowed it. To the charge of favoring standing armies, he responded:

If I had been charged with the design of establishing among you at public expense, a menagerie of two hundred thousand wild beasts, it would not have surprised me more, nor would it, in my judgment, have been one jot more preposterous.40

But the disavowal was not in time to avoid political damage in the ongoing presidential race. Poinsett's proposal was destined to be the last effort to nationalize the state militias until after the Civil War.41

The New Yorker's years in the White House saw the first national regulation of steamboats and a nationally funded scientific expedition. President Jackson had recommended "precautionary and penal legislation" after an explosion on a Red River steamboat in 1833 had killed Senator Josiah S. Johnston of Louisiana. Not until 1838 did Congress enact a law that required federal inspection of boilers and hulls on passenger vessels. They entrusted supervision to district judges, however; and the creation of a regular inspection bureaucracy within the Treasury Department had to await the future Whig presidency of Millard Fillmore.42 The navy's South Sea Exploring Expedition, under the command of Lieutenant Charles Wilkes, set sail in August 1838 on a four-year voyage that would claim discovery of Antarctica. But it had been the brainchild of former President John Quincy Adams, and Congress had appropriated the money nearly a year before Van Buren entered office.

To offset these relatively minor transgressions on market enterprise, the eighth president deserves credit for enthusiastically embracing reforms suggested by his postmaster general Amos Kendall of Kentucky. Kendall wanted to eliminate the heavy postal subsidy for newspapers, instituted back in 1792, which resulted in newspapers providing no more than 15 percent of postal revenue even though they accounted for more than 95 percent of deliveries by weight. The head of the Post Office also tried to rein in the congressional franking privilege. Needless to say, Congress was not interested in either of these reforms.43 Mention should be made of Van Buren's executive order; in the midst of his campaign for reelection, mandating a ten-hour day on all federal public works.

V - Political Defeat

The election of 1840 turned into a political circus. Under the savvy management of such rising Whig politicos as Thaddeus Stevens of Pennsylvania and Horace Greeley, William Seward, and Thurlow Weed of New York, the apologists for mercantilism learned to throw off the historic taint of elitist privilege and appeal for the first time directly to the masses. William Henry Harrison earned the sobriquet "General Mum" for obscure positions on the issues, while his party adopted no platform and emphasized its candidate's military record during the War of 1812 and his alleged frontier, log-cabin origins. Harrison was in reality the scion of Virginia aristocracy, but that did not stop the Whigs from falsely portraying Martin Van Buren as the effete grandee, extravagant with public money. The popular - rallies, colorful slogans, and huckster excitement surrounding the Whigs's "Log Cabin and Hard Cider" campaign caused the Democratic Review to cry out in despair: "We have taught them to conquer us!"44 Still, it was the lingering trauma of hard times, coupled with disgruntled Southern and Northern expansionism and the exaggerated fears of Democratic Caesarism, that brought about the Little Magician's political defeat at the hands of "Tippecanoe and Tyler too." Voter turnout was much higher in 1840 than four years earlier — jumping from 57.8 percent of those eligible to 80.2 percent — so that Van Buren actually received 400,000 more votes, but he carried only seven out of twenty — six states.45

Heading back to Kinderhook in March of 1841 with his usual good cheer, Van Buren felt confident of future vindication.

Instead, he would watch the Democracy abandon his peaceful foreign policy and, as a result, tear itself apart along with the Union, as he had foretold; he did not live to see his economic precepts go out of fashion as well. Nevertheless, the Little Magician could feel justifiable pride in his single term. Glyndon G. Van Deusen, a historian not at all sympathetic to laissez-faire, provides one of the fairest modern assessments:

[W]ith all his weaknesses, the fact remains that Van Buren was honest; that he knew the value of and habitually sought counsel; that he deliberated before making decisions; and that his four years in the White House demonstrated, for better or for worse, a perfectly logical development of the left-wing tendencies of Jacksonian Democracy a development which it took courage to foster in the face of a catastrophic depression.46

Defying the median voter model of public-choice theory, the eighth president moved, not toward the center, but risked political injury to become more radical while in office. As a result, this admirer of both Thomas Jefferson and Andrew Jackson presided himself over an administration marred by none of their inconsistencies. Nothing like the Sage of Monticello's despotic embargo, his unconstitutional Louisiana Purchase, or his vindictive witch-hunt against Aaron Burr disfigured the New Yorker's term. Nor anything to compare with Old Hickory's executive bullying of South Carolina, France, or Congress (to name just a few). The Little Magician remained truer to Old Republican principles than either of these more renowned known champions of liberty, even though the panic of 1837 arguably proffered as weighty a temptation for compromise.

Since Van Buren is being held up to a libertarian yardstick, perhaps it would be more appropriate to compare him with other nonactivist chief executives, those that mainstream historians tend to dismiss. Grover Cleveland, a later Democratic president who similarly confronted major depression, is actually in my opinion the strongest contender for superior accolades, but his signing the Interstate Commerce Act, his use of troops during the Pullman strike, and his involvement in the Venezuelan boundary dispute demonstrate a weaker commitment to free markets, civil liberties, and nonintervention. Warren Harding and Calvin Coolidge, it is true, implemented the brilliant fiscal program of Secretary of the Treasury Andrew Mellon, yet the economic meddling of their secretary of Commerce, Herbert Hoover, cancels that out. John Tyler looks good as long as you focus only on his vetoes; we have already mentioned the bills he signed and his Texas intrigue, to which you can add suppression of the Dorr Rebellion in Rhode Island. One thing alone disqualifies Millard Fillmore from consideration: the Fugitive Slave Act of 1850, among the most draconian laws Congress ever passed. As for Franklin Pierce and James Buchanan, even if we overlook their proslavery policies in Kansas, Pierce still has his imperialistic ambitions revealed in the Ostend Manifesto, whereas Buchanan stands indicted for dispatching the army to Utah in the Mormon War. And the single-term, post-Civil War Republicans — Rutherford B. Hayes, James A. Garfield, Chester A. Arthur, and Benjamin Harrison — with their high protective tariffs, pork-barrel subsidies, and profligate veterans' benefits, are not even in the running.

But the case for Van Buren's greatness goes beyond his being the least bad US president. While avoiding foreign wars, he did more than maintain the domestic status quo. He reduced the power and reach of central authority in the face of stiff resistance and thereby helped the American economy weather one of its most severe deflations. The Little Magician also brought an ideological clarity to American politics that has seldom been equaled. Although the Democracy would stray in significant and reprehensible ways from the principled course he had charted, his imprint still left an enduring legacy. The Democratic Party remained the political alliance with the strongest affinity for laissez-faire, personal liberty, and free trade until almost the turn of the century. All will acknowledge, I believe, that Americans once enjoyed greater freedom from government intervention than any other people on the face of the earth. For that accomplishment, Martin Van Buren deserves as much credit as any other single individual — and certainly more credit than any other president of the United States.

  • 1As quoted in William Cabell Bruce, John Randolph of Roanoke, 1773 – 1833:A Biography Based Largely on New Material (New York: G.P Putnam's Sons, 1922), vol. 2, p. 203; and John Niven, Martin Van Buren: The Romantic Age of American Politics (New York: Oxford University Press, 1983), p. 358.
  • 2Arthur M. Schlesinger, Jr., The Age of Jackson (Boston: Little, Brown, 1945), p. 263.
  • 3Three older biographies of Van Buren are Edward M. Shepard, Martin Van Buren, rev. ed. (Boston: Houghton, Mifflin, 1899), Denis Tilden Lynch, An Epoch and a Man: Martin Van Buren and His Times (New York: Horace Liveright, 1929), and Holmes Alexander, The American Talleyrand: The Career and Contemporaries of Martin Van Buren, Eighth President (New York: Harper and Brothers, 1935) — all of which give little space to his presidency. A more recent biography, John Niven's Martin Van Buren (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1983), is detailed and sympathetic. But Niven likewise races through the presidential years, and his treatment of ideological issues is often sparse or nonexistent. More attentive to ideas, although harsher in its judgments, is Donald B. Cole's political biography, Martin Van Buren and the American Political System (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1984). The best book on the Little Magician, however, is Major L. Wilson's magnificent The Presidency of Martin Van Buren (Lawrence: University Press of Kansas, 1984). Another volume devoted exclusively to Van Buren's presidency, James C. Curtis, The Fox at Bay: Martin Van Buren and the Presidency, 1837 – 1841 (Lexington: University Press of Kentucky, 1970), is more focused on politics than on analyzing economics. For Van Buren's earlier years, Robert V. Remini's Martin Van Buren and the Making of the Democratic Party (New York: WW Norton, 1959) is indispensable. Unfortunately, "The Autobiography of Martin Van Buren," Annual Report of the American Historical Association for the Year 1918, vol. 2, John C. Fitzpatrick, ed. (Washington, D.C.: US Government Printing Office, 1920), cuts off before the presidential years.
  • 4Morton Borden, ed., America's Ten Greatest Presidents (Chicago: Rand McNally, 1961), and Borden, ed., America's Eleven Greatest Presidents, 2nd ed. (Chicago: Rand McNally, 1971). The chosen ten (with asterisks indicating the wartime presidents) were Washington, Adams,* Jefferson, Jackson, Polk,* Lincoln,* Cleveland, T. Roosevelt, Wilson,* and F.D. Roosevelt.* Two others from this list might be considered wartime presidents as well, because the war with the Barbary pirates occurred during Jefferson's first term, and the United States was still suppressing the Filipino insurrection when Theodore Roosevelt assumed office. Borden based his initial choices on a 1948 poll of fifty-five historians, conducted by Arthur M. Schlesinger, Sr., and published in Life Magazine. Subsequent presidential ratings appear in Thomas A. Bailey, Presidential Greatness: The Image and the Man from George Washington to the Present (New York: Appleton – Century, 1966); Steve Neal, "Our Best and Worst Presidents," Chicago Tribune Magazine 135 (January 10, 1982): 9 – 18; and Robert K. Murray and Tim H. Blessing, Greatness in the White House: Rating the Presidents from George Washington through Ronald Reagan, 2nd ed. (University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press, 1994). Most recently, Arthur M. Schlesinger, Jr., reported on a recent presidential poll of historians in "The Ultimate Approval Rating," New York Times Magazine 146 (December 15, 1996): 46 – 51. The predominance of wartime presidents remains unaltered throughout all these efforts.
  • 5As quoted by Charles Sellers, The Market Revolution. Jacksonian America, 1815 – 1846 (New York Oxford University Press 1991), p. 415.
  • 6Both Curtis The Fox at Bay, pp. 152 – 88, and Wilson, The Presidency of Martin Van Buren, pp. 147 – 69, provide excellent coverage of Van Buren's foreign policy. For additional details on Texas and Mexico, consult Justin H. Smith, The War with Mexico, 2 vols (New York Macmillan, 1919), Smith, The Annexation of Texas, corrected ed. (New York Barnes and Noble, 1941), Frederick W. Merk, Slavery and the Annexation of Texas (New York Alfred A Knopf 1972), David M. Pletcher, The Diplomacy of Annexation Texas, Oregon, and the Mexican War (Columbia University of Missouri Press, 1973), and Jennifer Roback Morse "Constitutional Rules Political Accidents, and the Course of History New Light on the Annexation of Texas," Independent Review 2 (Fall 1997) 173 – 200.
  • 7As quoted in Curtis, The Fox at Bay, p. 185.
  • 8Again, Curtis and Wilson are fine accounts of Van Buren's diplomacy. Albert B. Corey's older work on The Crisis of 1830 – 1842 in Canadian-American Relations (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1941) can be somewhat unreliable on Van Buren's role. The best treatment of the disputes with Canada is Howard Jones, To the Webster — Ashburton Treaty: AStudy in Anglo-American Relations, 1783 – 66; Oscar A. Kinchen, The Rise and Fall of the Patriot Hunters (New York: Bookman Associates, 1956); John S.D. Eisenhower, Agent of Destiny: The Life and Times of General Winfield Scott (New York: Free Press, 1997), pp. 176 – 83, 195 –203; and Kenneth R. Stevens, Border Diplomacy: The Caroline and McLeod Affairs in Anglo-American Relations, 1837 – 1842 (Tuscaloosa: University of Alabama Press, 1989).
  • 9Wilson, The Presidency of Martin Van Buren, pp. 100, 145.
  • 10Ibid., p. 39.
  • 11James D. Richardson, ed., A Compilation of the Messages and Papers of the Presidents (New York: Bureau of National Literature, 1922), vol. 2, pp. 1536 – 37.
  • 12Ibid., p. 1561.
  • 13Ibid., p. 1547.
  • 14Ibid., pp. 1561 — 62. Van Buren also discussed the causes of the panic, in probably the most economically sophisticated presidential address ever penned. His explanation combined a rudimentary version of the Austrian trade cycle theory and a discerning presentation of the real-bills doctrine, along with an emphasis on the international factors that cliometricians have recently demonstrated to be decisive. On top of all that, the message made an objection to a national bank that remains still unanswered:
    In Great Britain where it has been seen the same causes have been attended with the same effects, a national bank possessing powers far greater than are asked for by the warmest advocates of such an institution here has also proved unable to prevent an undue expansion of credit and the evils that flow from it. (pp. 1545 – 46)
  • 15Congressional Globe, 25th Cong., 2nd sess. (January 3 1,1838) app. p. 606.
  • 16Thomas Hart Benton, Thirty Years' View: Or a History of the Working of the American Government for Thirty Years, From 1820 to 1850 (New York: D. Appleton, 1854 – 56), vol. 1, p. 657. Calhoun's role in putting distribution into the Deposit-Distribution Act of 1836 is revealed in John M. McFaul, The Politics of Jacksonian Finance (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1972), pp. 132 – 34, and Charles M. Wiltse, John C. Calhoun: Nullifier, 1829 – 1839 (Indianapolis, Ind.: Bobbs-Merrill, 1949), vol. 2, pp. 257 – 58, 265 – 67. Although Jackson himself had earlier toyed with the idea of distribution, his preferred plan was to eliminate the surplus by reducing tariffs and land prices, whereas the Democrats in Congress had proposed investing the surplus in state bonds. See Robert V. Remini, Andrew Jackson and the Course of American Democracy, 1833 – 1845 (New York: Harper and Row, 1984), pp. 322 – 25; Charles Grier Sellers, Jr., James K. Polk: Jacksonian, 1795 – 1843 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1957), pp. 223 – 33; Edward G. Bourne, The History of the Surplus Revenue of 1837: Being an Account of Its Origin, Its Distribution Among the States, and the Uses to Which It Was Applied (New York: G.E. Putnam's Sons, 1885); and Richard H. Timberlake, Jr., "The Specie Circular and Distribution of the Surplus," Journal of Political Economy 68 (April 1960): 109 – 17, which was revised and reprinted as chap. 5 of Timberlake, Monetary Policy in the United States: An Intellectual and Institutional History (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1993).
  • 17Wilson The Presidency of Martin Van Buren, offers the most complete (indeed almost the only) discussion of the alternative versions of the Independent Treasury and the differing views of its supporters. Schlesinger's The Age of Jackson, pp. 227 – 29, is still one of the best accounts of the intellectual origins of this idea, but also see Joseph Dorfman, The Economic Mind in American Civilization, 1606 – 1865 (New York: Viking Press, 1946), pp. 610-14. The Jacksonian hard-money theoretician, William M. Gouge, first proposed it in A Short History of Paper Money and Banking in the United States, (Philadelphia: T.W. Ustick, 1833). In 1834 Philadelphia economist Condy Raguet tried to interest members of Congress in the proposal, and Congressman William Fitzhugh Gordon of Virginia, a former Democrat who had followed Calhoun out of the party aired the idea in the House. Meanwhile Jackson's acting secretary of the treasury, Roger B. Taney, hired Gouge as a clerk in the department. Thus Calhoun's claim, endorsed by his biographer, Charles M. Wiltse in John C. Calhoun, vol. 2, pp. 343 – 61, that it was the Nullifier who prompted Van Buren into pushing the Independent Treasury is ludicrous.
  • 18For a revisionist defense that asserts the amount that the New York collector owed was only $200,000, exactly as much as he admitted to, see B.R. Brunson, The Adventures of Samuel Swartwout in the Age of Jefferson and Jackson (Lewiston, N.Y.: Edwin Mellen Press, 1989).
  • 19Wilson, The Presidency of Martin Van Buren, p. 113.
  • 20Richardson, ed., Messages and Papers of the Presidents, vol. 3, pp. 1762, 1766, 1769. Congress had already enacted a series of Jackson administration proposals designed to promote hard money: 1. an 1834 change in the mint ratio to encourage the circulation of gold coins; 2. an 1835 expansion of the United States Mint;3. a renewal of the legal-tender status of foreign coins; and4. a phased-in prohibition in the Deposit — Distribution Act of 1836 against the issue of small bank notes by government depositories, which replaced prohibitions the secretary of the Treasury had already administratively imposed.     See David A. Martin, "Metallism, Small Notes, and Jackson's War With the B.U.S.," Explorations in Economic History 11 (Spring 1974): 227 – 47. The hostility to small bank notes dated back to Mam Smith, it was not confined to hard-money advocates, and it was implemented by many state statutes. It was, however, at cross purposes with the new mint ratio, which tended after the California gold discoveries to drive silver coins out of circulation. Since silver coins were more suitable for small transactions, the interaction of the mint ratio with prohibitions on small notes created a shortage of cash in small denominations.    
         Timberlake, Monetary Policy in the United States, chap. 9, is the only economist to seriously examine this problem. The Coinage Act of 1853 subsequently tried to rectify the deficiency by authorizing subsidiary silver coins, but the economy still relied heavily on private alternatives. Details are in Neil Carothers, Fractional Money: A History of the Small Coins and Fractional Paper Currency of the United States (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1930).
  • 21Washington Globe (September 5, 1837), as quoted in Schlesinger, The Age of Jackson, p. 236.
  • 22The standard condemnation of the free-banking era is most readily accessible in Bray Hammond, Banks and Politics in America: From the Revolution to the Civil War (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1957). Subsequent research has so thoroughly overturned everything Hammond had to say about the politics of banking, and modern economic and financial theory has so thoroughly outdated all of his theoretical analysis, that it is astonishing that scholars still take this work seriously. The revisionist research on free banking has been spread mainly through journal articles, and three summaries are Larry J. Sechrest, Free Banking: Theory, History, and a Laissez-Faire Model (Westport, Conn.: Quorum Books, 1993), chap. 6; Kevin Dowd, "US Banking in the 'Free Banking' Period," in Dowd, ed., The Experience of Free Banking (London: Routledge, 1992); and Hugh Rockoff, "Lessons from the American Experience with Free Banking," in Unregulated Banking: Chaos or Order, Forrest Capie and Geoffrey E. Woods, eds. (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1991). Most contributions to this revision are either by Hugh Rockoff – "Money, Prices and Banks in the Jacksonian Era," in The Reinterpretation of American Economic History, Robert W. Fogel and Stanley L. Engerman, eds. (New York: Harper and Row, 1971), pp. 448 – 58; "American Free Banking Before the Civil War: A Reexamination," Journal of Economic History 32 (March 1972): 417 – 20; "New Evidence on Free Banking in the United States," American Economic Review 75 (September 1985): 886 – 89; and "The Free Banking Era: A Reexamination," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 6 (May 1974): 141 – 67 — or by Arthur J. Rolnick and Warren E. Weber, "Free Banking, Wildcat Banking, and Shinplasters," Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review (Fall 1982): 10 – 19; "New Evidence on the Free Banking Era," American Economic Review 73 (December 1983): 1080 – 91; "The Causes of Free Bank Failures: A Detailed Examination," Journal of Monetary Economics 14 (November 1984): 267 – 91; "Banking Instability and Regulation in the US Free Banking Era," Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review (Summer 1985): 2 – 9; and "Explaining the Demand for Free Bank Notes," Journal of Monetary Economics 21 (Winter 1986): 877 – 90.
  • 23Bray Hammond, Sovereignty and an Empty Purse: Banks and Politics in the Civil War (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1970), pp. 23, 24.
  • 24Works on the operation of the Independent Treasury include David Kinley, The History, Organization, and Influence of the Independent Treasury of the United States (New York: Thomas Y. Crowell, 1893); John Burton Phillips, "Methods of Keeping the Public Money of the United States," in Publications of the Michigan Political Science Association 4, no. 3; Ester Rogoff Taus, Central Banking Functions of the United States Treasury, 1789 – 1941 (New York: Russell and Russell, 1943); and Richard H. Timberlake, Jr., "The Independent Treasury and Monetary Policy before the Civil War," Southern Economic Journal 27 (October 1960): 92 – 103. (The Timberlake article is reprinted as chap. 6 in his Monetary Policy in the United States.) Subtreasury vaults for holding government funds formally lingered on until 1921, when the Federal Reserve System superseded them, but none of the motivating hard-money features remained. The Civil War's national banking system and Greenbacks had eviscerated the Independent Treasury.
  • 25B.U. Ratchford, American State Debts (Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press, 1941), pp. 77 – 134; Reginald Charles McGrane, Foreign Bondholders and American State Debts (New York Macmillan, 1935), and William A. Scoft, The Repudiation of State Debts: A Study in the Financial History of Mississippi, Florida, Alabama, North Carolina, South Carolina, Georgia, Louisiana,Arkansas, Tennessee, Minnesota, Michigan, and Virginia (New York Thomas Y. Crowell 1893)
  • 26US Department of Commerce, Historical Statistics of the United States: Colonial Times to 1970 (Washington, D.C.: US Government Printing Office, 1975), pt. 2, Series Y335 – 38.
  • 27Speech of Congressman J.A. Rockwell of Connecticut, Congressional Globe, 30th Cong., 1st Sess. (January 11, 1848) app. p. 106; "Appropriations and Expenditures for Public Buildings, Rivers and Harbors, Forts, Arsenals, Armories, and Other Public Works from March 4, 1789, to June 30, 1882," 47th Cong., 1st Sess (1881 – 82), Senate Executive Documents, no. 196, pp. 114, 286, 340, 521, 529.
  • 28Daniel Feller, The Public Lands in Jacksonian Politics (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1984), which supersedes both George M. Stephenson, The Political History of Public Lands from 1840 to 1862: From Pre-Emption to Homestead (Boston: Richard G. Badger, 1917), and Raynor G. Wellington, The Political and Sectional Influence of the Public Lands, 1828 – 1842 (Cambridge, Mass.: Riverside Press, 1914). Congress had passed the first preemption act in 1830, but it was retrospective, applying to past squafters on government land, and so required periodic renewal.
  • 29Van Buren, in December 1840 after his defeat for reelection, summarized what he felt were his administration's accomplishments. His fourth annual message to Congress listed "two-contested points in our public policy" that had dominated his term: "I allude to a national debt and a national bank…. Coming into office the declared enemy of both, I have earnestly endeavored to prevent a resort to either." Unwilling to raise taxes to balance the budget, Van Buren could claim: "The small amount of Treasury notes … still outstanding" is less "than the United States have in deposit with the States." Van Buren is here referring to the $28 million distributed to the states, technically in the form of a loan, by the Deposit-Distribution Act of 1836. Richardson, ed., Messages and Papers of the Presidents, vol. 3, pp. 1828 and 1824.
  • 30The best overall treatment of these economic fluctuations and their causes is Peter Temin, The Jacksonian Economy (New York: W.W. Norton, 1969). But also consult chap. 5 of Timberlake, Monetary Policy in the United States. Together Timberlake and Temin have demolished the traditional view that Jackson's Specie Circular brought on the banking crisis of 1837. As Timberlake concludes (p. 61), "[T]he Specie Circular was dramatic but inconsequential." However, Temin inexplicably rejects Timberlake's persuasive case that Clay's distribution of the surplus was a major contributing factor to the earlier panic. Additional details are in Reginald Charles McGrane, The Panic of 1837: Some Financial Problems of the Jacksonian Era (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1924); Walter Buckingham Smith and Arthur Harrison Cole, Fluctuations in American Business, 1790 – 1860 (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1935); Samuel Rezneck, "The Social History of an American Depression, 1837 – 1843," American Historical Review 40 (July 1935): 662 – 87 (reprinted as chap. 4 of Rezneck, Business Depressions and Financial Panics: Essays in American Business and Economic History [New York: Greenwood, 19681); George Macesich, "Sources of Monetary Disturbances in the US, 1834 – 1845," Journal of-Economic History 20 (September 1960): 407 – 34; and Rockoff "Money, Prices, and Banks in the Jacksonian Era." Although there are crude consumer price indices dating back to this period, I have followed Temin and other authorities in quoting the more reliable and extensive wholesale price indices. Presumably consumer prices would show less amplitude in their fluctuations. Non-economists tend automatically to assume that because the price decline was more severe after the suspension of 1839 than after 1837 that the resulting depression must also have been more severe. As we shall see, the evidence does not support this conclusion.
  • 31Most of this comparison is drawn from Temin, The Jacksonian Economy, p. 157. His table shows the money stock falling by 27 percent during the Great Depression, but that is because he is looking at Ml. If he had used M2 instead, which is more consistent with his nineteenth-century definition of the money stock, the two monetary contractions are of almost identical magnitudes. To get the 16 percent increase in output for 1839 – 1843, Temin relies on Robert E. Gallman's unpublished annual estimates of US GDP. Thomas Senior Berry offers less satisfactory estimates in Production and Population Since 1789: Revised GNP Series in Constant Dollars (Richmond, Va.: Bostwick Press, 1988), which yield only a 6 percent rise in output over the four years. Others who have noted similarities between the two episodes include Milton Friedman and Anna Jacobson Schwartz, A Monetary History of the United States, 1867 – 1960 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1963), p. 299; Douglass C. North, The Economic Growth of the United States, 1790 – 1860 (New York: Prentice Hall, 1961), p. 202; and Hammond, Banks and Politics in America, p. 529. Hammond as usual misinterprets the evidence and draws the wrong conclusion.
  • 32Hoover's contributions to price rigidity are exposed in three works by Murray Rothbard: "The Hoover Myth," in For a New America: Essays in History and Politics from Studies on the Left, 1959 – 1967, James Weinstein and David W Eakens, eds. (New York: Vmtage, 1970), pp. 162 – 79; "Herbert Hoover and the Myth of Laissez-Faire," in A New History of Leviathan:Essays on the Rise of the American Corporate State, Ronald Radosh and Murray Rothbard, eds. (New York: E.P Dutton, 1972), pp. 111 – 45; and America's Great Depression, 5th ed. (Auburn, Ala.: Mises Institute, 2000). See also Richard K. Vedder and Lowell E. Gallaway, Out of Work: Unemployment and Government in Twentieth-Century America, rev. ed. (New York: New York University Press, 1997), pp. 74 – 111, 128 – 49.
  • 33Charles Warren, Bankruptcy in United States History (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1935), pp. 56 – 85. A compromise bill, providing for both voluntary and involuntary bankruptcy but exempting corporations (which means all state-chartered banks), passed the Senate on June 25, 1840, while Van Buren was still in office, but was rejected by the Democratic-controlled House. The Whigs were only able in 1841 to pass a similar measure with some blatant logrolling, in which Western votes for bankruptcy were bought with the promise of Eastern votes for distribution.
  • 34Ronald N. Satz, American Indian Policy in the Jacksonian Era (Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press, 1975); Francis Paul Prucha, The Sword of theRepublic: The United States Army on the Frontier, 1783 – 1846 (New York: Macmillan, 1969), pp. 249 – 306; John K. Mahon, History of the Second Seminole War, 1835 – 1842 (Gainesville: University of Florida Press, 1967); Grant Foreman, Indian Removal: The Emigration of the Five Civilized Tribes of Indians (Norman: University of Oklahoma Press, 1932). The authorized increase in the regular army took effect in July 1838, but an examination of the US Department of Commerce, Historical Statistics of the United States, pt. 2, Series Y904-16, reveals that total army personnel had risen to 12,449 by 1837. That is because the Seminole War had already induced Congress to authorize in May 1836, while Jackson was still president, enlistment of 10,000 additional emergency troops to serve for six to twelve months.
  • 35As quoted by Van Buren in his first inaugural, Richardson, ed., Messagesand Papers of the Presidents, vol. 2, p. 1535.
  • 36William Lee Miller, Arguing About Slavery: The Great Battle in the United States Congress (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1996); Howard Jones, Mutiny on the Amistad: The Saga of a Slave Revolt and Its Impact on American Abolition, Law, and Diplomacy (New York: Oxford University Press, 1987); and Mary Cable, Black Odyssey: The Case of the Slave Ship Amistad (New York: Viking Press, 1971).
  • 37Cole, Martin Van Buren and the American Political System, pp. 362 – 63; Wilson, The Presidency of Martin Van Buren, p. 200.
  • 38Richard H. Brown, "The Missouri Crisis, Slavery, and the Politics of Jacksonianism," South Atlantic Quarterly 65 (Winter 1966): 55 – 72, is an influential but simplistic argument that Martin Van Buren's Democracy was intentionally and unequivocally proslavery – an argument which is echoed in Leonard L. Richards, "The Jacksonians and Slavery," in Antislavery Reconsidered: New Perspectives on the Abolitionists, Lewis Perry and Michael Fellman, eds. (Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press, 1979), pp. 99 – 118. For more sophisticated and balanced considerations of this question, see John McFaul, "Expediency vs. Morality: Jacksonian Politics and Slavery," Journal of American History 62 (June 1975): 24 – 39; William H. Riker, Liberalism Against Populism: A Confrontation Between the Theory of Democracy and the Theory of Social Choice (San Francisco: W.H. Freeman, 1982), pp. 213 – 32; William W Freehling, The Road to Disunion:Secessionists at Bay, 1776 – 1854 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1990), pp. 287 – 352; J. David Greenstone, The Lincoln Persuasion: Remaking American Liberalism (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1993), pp. 154 – 85 and Sean Wilentz "Slavery Antislavery, and Jacksoman Democracy, in The Market Revolution in America Social, Political, and Religious Expressions, 1800 – 1880, Melvyn Stokes and Stephen Conway, eds. (Charlottesville University Press of Virginia, 1996), pp. 202 – 23.
  • 39Stevens, Border Diplomacy, pp. 27 – 28.
  • 40As quoted in Curtis, The Fox at Bay, p. 201.
  • 41Marcus Cunliffe, Soldiers and Civilians: The Martial Spirit in America,1775 – 1865 (Boston: Little, Brown, 1968), pp. 197 – 99; Russell E. Weigley, History of the United States Army (New York: Macmillan, 1967), pp. 156 – 57; J. Fred Rippy, Joel R. Poinsett: Versatile American (Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press, 1935), pp. 175 – 77; Curtis, The Fox at Bay, pp. 199 – 201; Wilson, The Presidency of Martin Van Buren, pp. 188 – 89. For background on the evolution of the militia during this period, consult John K. Mahon, History of the Militia and National Guard (New York: Macmillan, 1983), pp. 63 – 96.
  • 42Leonard D. White, The Jacksonians: A Study in Administrative History, 1829 – 1861 (New York Free Press, 1954), pp. 442 – 46, Lloyd M. Short, Steamboat-Inspection Service: Its History, Activities and Organization (New York: D. Appleton, 1922) pp. 1 – 6, John H. Morrison, History of American Steam Navigation (New York: W.F. Sametz, 1903) pp. 591 – 92. Neither Curtis, The Fox at Bay nor Wilson, The Presidency of Martin Van Buren, mentions this regulatory development. To my knowledge, there is no economic study of steamboat inspection's efficacy, but we may safely assume that it was as inefficient and counterproductive as nearly all other federal regulation.
  • 43Richard R. John, Spreading the News: The American Postal System from Franklin to Morse (Cambridge, Mass Harvard University Press, 1995), p. 40, passim. Wilson, The Presidency of Martin Van Buren, pp. 172 – 75.
  • 44As quoted in Glyndon G. Van Deusen, The Jacksonian Era, 1828 – 1848 (New York: Harper and Brothers, 1959), p. 148.
  • 45Robert Gray Gunderson, The Log-Cabin Campaign (Lexington: University of Kentucky Press, 1957), and Michael F. Holt, "The Election of 1840, Voter Mobilization, and the Emergence of the Second American Party System: A Reappraisal of Jacksonian Voting Behavior," in Holt, Political Parties and American Political Development: From the Age of Jackson to the Age of Lincoln (Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press, 1992), pp. 151 – 91. See also articles by Joel H. Silbey, "Election of 1836," and William Nisbet Chambers, "Election of 1840," both in History of American Presidential Elections, Arthur M. Schlesinger, Jr., Fred L. Israel, and William P. Hansen, eds. (New York: Chelsea House, 1971), vol. 1.
  • 46Van Deusen, The Jacksonian Era, p. 114.

CITE THIS ARTICLE

Hummel, Jeffrey Rogers, "Martin Van Buren: The American Gladstone," in Reassessing the Presidency: The Rise of the Executive State and the Decline of Freedom, ed. John V. Denson (Auburn, Ala.: Mises Institute, 2001), chap. 6.

All Rights Reserved ©
What is the Mises Institute?

The Mises Institute is a non-profit organization that exists to promote teaching and research in the Austrian School of economics, individual freedom, honest history, and international peace, in the tradition of Ludwig von Mises and Murray N. Rothbard. 

Non-political, non-partisan, and non-PC, we advocate a radical shift in the intellectual climate, away from statism and toward a private property order. We believe that our foundational ideas are of permanent value, and oppose all efforts at compromise, sellout, and amalgamation of these ideas with fashionable political, cultural, and social doctrines inimical to their spirit.

Become a Member
Mises Institute