Mises Daily

Freedom and Sound Money

"It is impossible to grasp the meaning of the idea of sound money if one does not realize that it was devised as an instrument for the protection of civil liberties against despotic inroads on the part of governments. Ideologically it belongs in the same class with political constitutions and bills of right."1

So wrote Ludwig von Mises in The Theory of Money and Credit in 1912. And further: "(...) the sound-money principle has two aspects. It is affirmative in approving the market's choice of a commonly used medium of exchange. It is negative in obstructing the government's propensity to meddle with the currency system."2  Against this backdrop, modern day's monetary systems appear to have been drifting farther and farther away from the sound money principle in the last decades.

In all countries of the so-called "free world," money represents nowadays a government controlled irredeemable paper, or "fiat," money standard. The widely held view is that this money system would be compatible with the ideal of a free society and conducive to sustainable output and employment growth. To be sure, there are voices calling for caution. Taking a historical viewpoint, Milton Friedman stated: "(...) the world is now engaged in a great experiment to see whether it can fashion a different anchor, one that depends on government restraint rather than on the costs of acquiring a physical commodity."3  Irving Fisher, evaluating past experience, wrote: "Irredeemable paper money has almost invariably proved a curse to the country employing it."4

The primary cause for concern rests on a key characteristic of government controlled paper money: the system's unrestrained ability to expand money and credit supply. In contrast, under the (freely chosen) gold standard, money (e.g. gold) supply was expected to increase as well over time, but only in proportion to how the economy expanded — i.e. an increase in money demand, brought about by an increase in economic activity, would bring additional gold supply to the market (by, for instance, increased mining which would become increasingly profitable). As such, the gold standard puts an "automatic break" on money expansion — the latter would be, at least in theory, related to the economy's growth trend.

The government controlled fiat money system has no inherent limit to money and credit expansion. In fact, quite the opposite holds true: Central banks, the monopolistic suppliers of governments' money, have actually been deliberately designed to be able to change money and credit supply by actually any amount at any time.

To prevent abuse of their unlimited power over the quantity of money supply, most central banks have been granted political independence over the past decades. This has been done in order to keep politicians who, in order to get re-elected, from trading off the benefits of a monetary policy induced stimulus to the economy against future costs in the form of inflation. In addition, many central banks have been mandated to seek low and stable inflation — measured by consumer price indices — as their primary objective. These two institutional factors — political independency and the mandate to preserve the purchasing power of money — are now widely seen as proper guarantees for preserving sound money.

Be that as it may, Mises's concerns appear as relevant as ever: "The dissociation of the currencies from a definitive and unchangeable gold parity has made the value of money a plaything of politics. (...) We are not very far now from a state of affairs in which "economic policy" is primarily understood to mean the question of influencing the purchasing power of money."5

Whereas the objective to preserve the value of government controlled paper money appears to be a laudable one, the truth is that it is (virtually) impossible to deliver on such a promise. In fact, there are often overwhelming political-economic incentives for a society to increase its money and credit supply, if possible, in order to influence societal developments according to ideological pre-set designs rather than relying on free market principles.

This very tendency is particularly evidenced by the fact that central banks are regularly called upon to take into account output growth and the economy's job situation when setting interest rates. And these considerations are what seem to cause severe problems in a paper money system if and when there is no clear-cut limit to money and credit expansion.

To bring home this point, it is instructive to take a brief look at the relationship between credit and nominal output and "wealth" growth (which is defined here, for simplicity, as gross domestic product plus stock market capitalisation) in the US, the euro area and Japan since the early 1980s. A visual inspection reveals that in the US, the relationship between domestic credit and nominal output growth is relatively weak. If, however, credit expansion is plotted against wealth growth, we see that these two variables are actually quite closely related.

In the euro area, bank loan and output growth were relatively closely aligned up until the early 1990s. In the period 1995 to late 2000, though, credit and output growth seemed to have decoupled quite markedly: Whereas loan growth went up strongly, nominal output growth remained fairly stabilized. If, however, bank loan growth is plotted against wealth expansion, the correlation seems to be more evident, especially during the second half of the 1990s.

In Japan, domestic credit expansion appears to be strongly correlated to changes in nominal output. The relationship between changes in credit and changes in wealth, however, appears much less pronounced (especially when compared to the constellation in the US). All the same, it appears that the decline in domestic credit around the end of the 1980s has been accompanied by a (trend) decline in nominal wealth growth.

Looking at the data, the overriding message seems to be: an increase in credit supply has, on average, been accompanied by an increase in nominal output and/or wealth and vice versa. It is tempting to draw a simple conclusion from these findings, indeed: changes in monetary policy do not appear to be "neutral" when it comes to exerting an effect on peoples' dispositions; in fact, monetary policy induced increases in money and credit supply might be sooner or later accompanied by changes in economic activity.6

But a money and credit supply induced stimulus to the economy is short-lived, insights from the classical economic theory warn, and will eventually lead to inflation — as outlined by David Hume in 1742: "augmentation (in the quantity of money) has no other effect than to heighten the price of labour and commodities. (...) in the progress towards these changes, the augmentation may have some influence, by exciting industry, but after the prices are settled (...) it has no manner of influence."7

However, the intellectual conviction of the economic mainstream, which is dominated by Keynesian Economics, is that by lowering interest rates the central bank can stimulate growth and employment. So it does not take wonder that, especially so in periods in which inflation is seen to be "under control," central banks are pressured into an "expansionary" monetary policy to fight recession. In fact, it is widely considered "appropriate" if monetary policy keeps borrowing costs at the lowest level possible.

In the work of Mises one finds a well-founded criticism of this broadly held conviction. He writes: "(...) public opinion is prone to see in interest nothing but a merely institutional obstacle to the expansion of production. It does not realize that the discount of future goods as against present goods is a necessary and eternal category of human action and cannot be abolished by bank manipulation. In the eyes of cranks and demagogues, interest is a product of the sinister machinations of rugged exploiters. The age-old disapprobation of interest has been fully revived by modern interventionism. It clings to the dogma that it is one of the foremost duties of good government to lower the rate of interest as far as possible or to abolish it altogether. All present-day governments are fanatically committed to an easy money policy."8

Mises also outlines what the propensity to lower interest rates and increasing money and credit supply does to the economy. The Austrian School of Economics' "Monetary Theory of the Trade Cycle" maintains that it is monetary expansion which is at the heart of the economies' boom and bust cycles. Overly generous supply of money and credit induces what is usually called an "economic upswing". It is wake, economic growth increases and employment rises.

With the liquidity flush, however, come misalignments, a distortion of relative prices, so the theoretical reasoning is. Sooner or later, the artificial money and credit supply-fuelled expansion is unsustainable and turns into a recession. In ignorance and/or in failing to identify the very forces responsible for the economic malaise, namely excessive money and credit creation in the past, falling output and rising unemployment provoke public calls for an even easier monetary policy.

Central banks are not in a position to withstand such demands if they do not have any "anchoring" — that is a (fixed) rule which restrains the increase in money and credit supply in day-to-day operations. In the absence of such a limit, central banks, confronted with a severe economic crisis, are most likely to be forced to trade off the growth and employment objective against the preserving the value of money — thereby compromising a crucial pillar of the free society.

Seen against this backdrop, today's monetary policy actually resembles a "ruleless" undertaking. The Zeitgeist holds that "inflation targeting" (IT) — the so-called "state-of-the-art" concept from the point of view of most central banks — will do the trick to prevent monetary policy from causing unintended trouble. In practice, however, IT does not have any external anchor. Under IT, it is the central bank itself that calculates inflation forecasts which, in turn, determine how the bank set interest rates; setting a quantitative limit to money and credit expansion is usually not seen as a policy objective. IT can thus hardly inspire confidence that it will mitigate the threat to the value of paper money stemming from governments (in the form of fraud/misuse) and/or politically independent monetary policy makers (in the form of policy mistakes).

The return to "monetary policy without rule" began in the early 1990s, when various central banks abandoned monetary aggregates as a major guide post for setting interest rates. It was argued that "demand for money" had become an unstable indicator in the "short term" and that, as such, money could no longer be used as a yardstick in setting monetary policy, particularly so as policy makers were making interest rate decisions every few weeks. However, that guide post has not been replaced with anything since then.

In view of the return of discretion in monetary policy, it might be insightful to quote Hayek's concern, namely that: "(...) [inflation] is the inevitable result of a policy which regards all the other decisions as data to which the supply of money must be adapted so that the damage done by other measures will be as little noticed as possible." In the long run, such a policy would cause central banks to become "the captives of their own decisions, when others force them to adopt measures that they know to be harmful."

Echoing the warning that Ludwig von Mises gave back in The Theory of Money and Credit, Hayek concluded: "The inflationary bias of our day is largely the result of the prevalence of the short-term view, which in turns stems from the great difficulty of recognising the more remote consequences of current measures, and from the inevitable preoccupation of practical men, and particularly politicians, with the immediate problems and the achievements of near goals."9

What can we learn from all this? The inherent risks of today's paper money standard — the very ability of expanding the stock of money and credit at will by actually any amount at any time — are no longer paid proper attention: Putting a limit on the expansion of money and credit does not rank among the essential ingredients for "modern" monetary policy making. The discretionary handling of paper money thus increases the potential for a costly failure substantially. A first step for moving back towards the sound money principle — which is doing justice to the ideal of a free society — would be to make monetary policy limiting, eg, stopping altogether, money supply growth.

  • 1Mises, L. von (1912), The Theory of Money and Credit, p. 454.
  • 2Ibid, p. 455.
  • 3Friedman, M. (1994), Money Mischief, San Diego et al., p. 42.
  • 4Fisher, I. (1929), The Purchasing Power of Money, New York, Macmillan, 1911, 2nd ed., New York, Macmillan, 1913, New ed., New York: Macmillan 1929, p. 131.
  • 5Ibid, p. 27.
  • 6Of course, the data do not say anything about causality — that is whether credit induces nominal activity or whether it is the other way round. Also, they do not answer the question as to whether changes in monetary policy action induce "well behaved" reactions. In fact, Friedrich August von Hayek noted: "Its stimulus is due to the errors which it produces." Hayek, F. A. von (1960), The Constitution of Liberty, Chicago, Chicago Press, p. 332.
  • 7Hume, D. (1742), Of Interest, in: Essays, Moral, Political and Literary, Vol. 1 of Essays and Treatises. A new ed. Edinburgh: Bell & Bradfute, Cadell & Davis (1804), p. 314.
  • 8Mises, L. von (1996), Human Action, 4th edition, Fox & Wilkes, Ludwig von Mises Institute, p. 572.
  • 9Hayek, F. A. von (1960), p. 333.
All Rights Reserved ©
What is the Mises Institute?

The Mises Institute is a non-profit organization that exists to promote teaching and research in the Austrian School of economics, individual freedom, honest history, and international peace, in the tradition of Ludwig von Mises and Murray N. Rothbard. 

Non-political, non-partisan, and non-PC, we advocate a radical shift in the intellectual climate, away from statism and toward a private property order. We believe that our foundational ideas are of permanent value, and oppose all efforts at compromise, sellout, and amalgamation of these ideas with fashionable political, cultural, and social doctrines inimical to their spirit.

Become a Member
Mises Institute