Mises Wire

Does the Fed Follow Its Own Rules?

One of the most interesting discussions in the field of monetary theory concerns the role central banks play in the economy. There are multiple views regarding different issues: from questioning the mere existence of the central bank to the actual role a central bank should take. An engaging issue is whether the central bank — if one is justified — should be autonomous from political power. Another issue of great significance regards the form the central bank’s interventions should take: Should the central bank’s governing body have its own discretion? Should it be driven by impersonal rules instead of people?

Throughout the history of the central bank, different rules have been implemented to avoid giving discretion to the central bank. Some examples of these rules are the Palmer rule, the Bagehot rule, and the Friedman rule. The most modern and most popular central bank rule is the Taylor rule, which came about in the early 90s.

The Taylor Rule

Since it was invented, the Taylor rule became popular with the Fed. In 1995, Janet Yellen claimed she used the Taylor rule as a guide to know whether interest rates were at an acceptable level. According to Taylor himself, the Fed was already following precepts of the Taylor rule since 1987.1  The rule was monitored by the Fed since 1993 and was explicitly implemented in 1995.

The Taylor rule assumes that central banks use fixed discount rates as the main monetary policy tool — as most of the world’s central banks do today. The Taylor rule is a guide for setting interest rates, taking into account different economic variables.

The Taylor rule takes into account the following three variables when setting the “optimal” interest rate:2

  • Actual inflation and real short-term interest rate.3
  • The difference between targeted inflation and actual inflation.
  • Difference between actual employment and the full employment level.

The first variable comes from the assumption that the real interest rate and the nominal interest rate have a different level of inflation.

The second variable is the inflation differential. It assumes that below target inflation can be offset by lowering the interest rate and causing a credit increase. The increase in credit causes inflationary pressures. As the gap between actual inflation and targeted inflation closes, the Fed’s interest rate should rise.

The third variable is the employment differential: the difference between the lowest unemployment rate attainable and the actual unemployment rate. In other versions of the Taylor rule, this variable should be the difference between potential economic growth and actual economic growth. The idea is the same: if unemployment rises — or if there is economic growth below its potential — the interest rate should fall. A decrease in the interest rate reduces the cost of credit and allows less profitable projects to be carried out by hiring more employees and increasing economic activity.

The purpose of this article is not to discuss whether the Taylor rule is convenient (ideally the central bank should not set the interest rate, instead it should be established by the market).

How well does the Fed follow the Taylor rule?

Although Alan Greenspan never fully agreed with the need to link monetary policy to rules, the Fed generally follows the Taylor rule as a way to avoid excesses in the management of monetary policies.

The question we ask is the following: has the Fed followed the rule it imposed on itself since the mid-1990s?

Currently, the Taylor rule indicates that the discount rate in the US should be at 3.94%. However, the federal funds rate set by the Federal Reserve is at 1%. Therefore, it seems the Fed is not currently following the Taylor rule.

Consider the last 20 years in the next graph, which links the interest rate promoted by the Taylor rule and the federal funds interest rate set by the Fed.

Source: Bloomberg. Blue: Taylor rule interest rate. Orange: Federal funds rate

There seems to be two distinct periods: a first period until 2009 and second one from 2009 to the present. In the former, the Fed seems to follow the Taylor rule — although not accurately; in the latter period the Taylor rule is completely ignored.

However, if we look at the same graph in terms of the differential — Taylor rule interest rate vs. Fed interest rate — we see how the Fed has had significant deviations in the implementation of the rule throughout the period.

Source: Bloomberg. Taylor rule spread — FED funds rate. Side:

Even before 2009, for years the set interest rate was as far as 2% from the interest rate recommended by the Taylor rule. Deviations accelerated in 2009, when interest rates reached 0% and it became less feasible to follow the Taylor rule — although the European bank did not hesitate to reduce rates below 0%.

The Great Recession and the death of the Taylor rule

The great recession has made it more difficult to follow the Taylor rule when it recommends negative interest rates. The Fed has not wanted to implement negative interest rates as willingly as the European Central Bank.

Yet, since 2012 it became feasible to follow the Taylor rule once more, as interest rate recommendations returned to the positive territory. Nevertheless, it doesn’t look like Ben Bernanke or Janet Yellen made a serious attempt to follow this rule.

In fact, Yellen — who previously supported the Taylor rule — now explicitly rejects it under the premise that we can’t know the true value of the real interest rate and that it could potentially distort the money market.

It is curious that Yellen adopted the same opinion Greenspan held when he was in the same position. From a public choice view, it is perfectly understandable that the ruler of the central bank should reject any limit to his power. The Taylor rule, after all, restricts the Fed’s ability to act.

Conclusion

It seems that centuries of monetary disasters have led to a consensus in which the management of the central banks should be carried out without any interference from political powers. However, it is not easy to get an independent central bank, even behind the most technical speeches there are hidden political agendas.

The rules set a technical and ex-ante criterion for monetary policy, in such a way that political actors are constrained in their ability to influence the central bank’s governing body, and economic agents know in advance what the monetary policy will be and can adapt to it. In other words, these rules are intended to create a climate of trust.

The Fed formally adhered to the Taylor rule since 1995. However, it has never followed it with determination. Discretion seems to be the norm in the management of US monetary policy.

Reprinted from UFM Market Trends. 
  • 1Although the Taylor rule came about later on, versions of it were being discussed in academic circles.
  • 2There are several versions of the Taylor rule, the one explained here has probably been the most relevant when making monetary policy decisions.
  • 3 It is assumed that short-term interest rate is equal to long-term economic growth, 2% for developed economies.
image/svg+xml
Note: The views expressed on Mises.org are not necessarily those of the Mises Institute.
Support Liberty

The Mises Institute exists solely on voluntary contributions from readers like you. Support our students and faculty in their work for Austrian economics, freedom, and peace.

Donate today
Group photo of Mises staff and fellows