Mises Wire

David Howden on Fama and Shiller and Asset Prices

David Howden on Fama and Shiller and Asset Prices

Guest Post:The Great Nobel Heist of 2013
By David Howden

The paradox of the awarding of the 1974 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Science is really just par for the course. Friedrich Hayek and Gunnar Myrdal shared the prize that year – both for their work on monetary fluctuations and the business cycle. While there were some affinities between the two early in their careers: both used a Wicksellian foundation, stressed the importance of Knightian uncertainty and the role of ex ante expectations versus ex post results in investment decisions. But by the time the elder economists won their Nobels they were almost polar opposites. Hayek had moved to his work on to the social order of a free society while Myrdal had taken on a decidedly more socialistic bent.

This year’s Nobel Prize is shared between three eminent economists, Eugene Fama, Lars Peter Hansen and Robert Shiller. For the purposes of this article commemorating their achievement, I wish to compare Fama and Shiller’s accomplishments, contributions and what the Prize really represents. As we shall see, though both academics won the award for their work on asset prices, their results and conclusions couldn’t be more at odds with each other.

Fama is most famous for this work on the efficient-market hypothesis (EMH). Loosely stated, markets are efficient when all relevant information pertaining to a business is factored into and reflected in its stock’s price. Since future information concerning the stock is not yet known, and cannot be known, there is no way that any investor can “beat” the market. Fama built on this conclusion, and went one step further. Not only can one not beat the market, but any market return will be random – the unknowable nature of the future implies that any stock’s price must follow an unpredictable “random walk”

Such a conception of knowledge and efficiency seriously misconstrues the nature of both concepts. For EMH to hold true, not only must all knowledge be interpreted in the same way by all investors, but the impact of that knowledge must also be identical among everyone! The first statement removes any subjective element from knowledge formation, and in its place the theory is built upon an objective element. The latter statement implies no differences in investors – everyone must have the same goals, interpret new knowledge in an identical way, and even have an identical time preference scale. (Interested readers can see my previous work on EMH (pdf) here and here.)

If EMH is a boring fairytale describing how people could act under the most unrealistic of conditions and how markets are efficient as a result, Shiller’s work revolves around searching for ways that markets are inefficient.

One of Shiller’s best known works is his 1981 article titled “Do Stock Prices Move Too Much To Be Justified By Subsequent Changes In Dividends?” in which he challenged the dominant position of the efficient-market hypothesis. His subsequent work looked at what role behavioral aspects create economic bubbles.

In many ways, Shiller is one of the most forceful characters in behavioral finance. Some key themes of this sub-discipline is the belief that economic agents make decisions based on simple heuristics and rules of thumbs, in contrast to logic. Behaviorists believe that how a person frames a problem (i.e., stereotypes it) will determine how he responds to an event in addition to the cold, hard relevant facts. Finally, a mainstay of traditional behavioral economics is the belief that markets are, or at least can be, inefficient – whether this be by asset mispricings (mistakes) or non-rational decision making.

It is not a stretch to state that behavioral economics has nothing in common with EMH.

Outside of the ivory tower, Shiller is likely best known for his 2000 book, Irrational Exuberance. Starting from the belief that investors are subject to fits of, well, irrational exuberance, Shiller wrote how the apparent stock market bubble at the time was caused by investors unrealistically setting their expectations of future returns not on any fundamental event, but rather on their own out-of-control beliefs concerning future growth.

Interestingly, Eugene Fama was a stark critic of the book and Shiller’s approach, commenting that “Bob … has been consistently pessimistic about prices.” Indeed, in the same interview Fama boasted of having cancelled his subscription to The Economist because of the magazine’s overuse of the phrase “bubble.” This was on April 26, 2010, less than a year and half of a crisis that almost every commentator, economist and layman would say was precipitated by a bubble in sovereign debt, personal borrowing, and housing prices.

Indeed, Philipp Bagus and I had similarly harsh words about Shiller in our review (pdf) of his 2008 book The Subprime Solution. We not only chastised Shiller’s total neglect of reduced underwriting standards and extreme credit creation as causes of the crisis, but also of his recommendation that the U.S. government implement a new New Deal. In nominal spending terms the U.S. government has done just this over the past five years, and we can see what good it has done the economy. (As well as the debt overhang it has created for future generations of Americans.)

Eugene Fama and Robert Shiller have almost nothing in common, short of both being well known economists who work in the broad field of asset pricing. Their approaches are diametrically opposed to each other. Their predictions about asset prices and the ability of economic agents to make informed and “correct” decisions could not differ more, yet they are the co-recipients of this year’s Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel.

Unlike in real life, the Nobel committee and the economists it showers praise on are not constrained by an unfortunate fact of life: losses. The investment world is not about armchair theorizing. Investors price assets based on models predicated on both EMH and behavioral aspects. The pension funds of widows and orphans are run by bankers and economists trained in the spirit of these Nobel laureates’ works.

This year’s Prize is a heist. Both Fama and Shiller may be praised for their work which is judged as insightful independent of its usefulness or correctness, but others of us know better. Bad theories that cause losses matter. Worse yet is the misplaced credibility that this Prize bestows to its recipients.

Five years ago, President Barack Obama was awarded the Nobel Peace Prize for his “extraordinary efforts” in establishing international cooperation. We have seen how that turned out, and one beneficial side effect is that this unearned award brought the whole Nobel committee and process into disrepute. Let’s hope that this year’s recipients can have the same effect on the prestige of the economics Nobel.

All Rights Reserved ©
What is the Mises Institute?

The Mises Institute is a non-profit organization that exists to promote teaching and research in the Austrian School of economics, individual freedom, honest history, and international peace, in the tradition of Ludwig von Mises and Murray N. Rothbard. 

Non-political, non-partisan, and non-PC, we advocate a radical shift in the intellectual climate, away from statism and toward a private property order. We believe that our foundational ideas are of permanent value, and oppose all efforts at compromise, sellout, and amalgamation of these ideas with fashionable political, cultural, and social doctrines inimical to their spirit.

Become a Member
Mises Institute