Mises Wire

How Government Spending Can Make the Debt Burden Look Smaller than It Really Is

In economics, numbers without context are often difficult to understand. The price of apples can only be understood when compared to the price of oranges, or to your salary, or to yesterday’s price. This is especially true with astronomically high numbers, such as $23 trillion. As of April 16, 2020, the US national debt1   stands at this amount. If we split it evenly among the working-age US population (15–64), it corresponds to a lump-sum tax of $118,000 per person.2  The national debt is almost always reported as a fraction of the gross domestic product (GDP). What is not always known is how these quantities are defined, and here lies my interest.

Understanding debt is straightforward: it is the money the government borrows to finance expenses that exceed tax revenue.3   Let’s move on to the denominator, the GDP. From the International Monetary Fund, the most common formulation of GDP is: The value of purchases made by final users—for example, the consumption of food, televisions, and medical services by households; the investments in machinery by companies; and the purchases of goods and services by the government and foreigners.

In a formula:

GDP = C + I + (X – M) + G

According to this formula, GDP, or the nation’s production, is the sum of consumption, investments, exports (minus imports), and government spending.4   If you divide the US debt by the sum of these four elements, you get a debt-to-GDP ratio of 107 percent for 2019. This is the regular procedure and how this data is read.

Now, consider some hypothetical worlds with different economic realities. If US consumers were to invest more and consume less (assume the two effects are equal in size), GDP wouldn’t change. If China produced for domestic consumption rather than for export, GDP wouldn’t change. If Germans decided they have saved enough and started consuming more, GDP wouldn’t change. These decisions imply shifts on a global scale, but they simply reflect a reallocation of resources toward more desired ends. The standards of living would be expected, if anything, to increase. These would be purposeful decisions, a priori beneficial.

Now assume a different set of economic realities. What if people reduced consumption and the government decided to offset this by increasing its consumption by the same amount? What if people stopped investing (perhaps due to thirteen years of zero interest rates) and the government decided to handpick which companies deserve funding?5  From the basic formula it would look like nothing has changed, as in the previous examples. But there’s a problem here. In Human Action Mises writes:

There is need to emphasize the truism that a government can only spend or invest what it takes away from its citizens and that its additional spending and investment curtails the citizens’ spending and investment to the full extent of its quantity.

While government has no power to make people more prosperous by interference with business, it certainly does have the power to make them less satisfied by restriction of production. (p. 737)

This is a key reason why government spending isn’t really the same as private spending or saving. A second reason is that people are moved by self-interest and the desire to avoid losses, while the government doesn’t care about funding junk zombie companies: losses would be offloaded through taxation or inflation. Further reasons could fill a book, but I think this brief explanation is sufficient.

I propose a simple solution to this measurement problem: focus on private GDP only. That is, look at private gross domestic product (PGDP):

PGDP = C + I + (X – M)

This is GDP but without government spending.6

This measure is similar to the gross domestic private product of Robert Higgs, who reasoned as follows:

Why should government product be excluded? First, the government’s activities may be viewed as giving rise to intermediate, rather than final products….Second, because most government services are not sold in markets, they have no market-determined prices to be used in calculating their total value to those who benefit from them. Third, because many government services arise from political, rather than economic motives and institutions, some of them may have little or no value. Indeed, some commentators—including the present writer—ultimately went so far as to assert that some government services have negative value.

Murray Rothbard in Power and Market similarly asserted that:

[The GDP calculation] fallaciously assumes that the government’s “product” is measurable by what the government spends. On what possible basis can this assumption be made?…The government’s tax revenue and deficit are both burdens imposed on production. (p. 1293)

Government Dept as a Proportion of Private GDP

Now, let’s compare government debt with PGDP. The ratio of debt to PGDP has a clear interpretation: the burden of the public debt towers; below is how the people earn their salaries to pay taxes. There is no more ambiguity now: previously you could think that government spending can increase GDP faster than debt; now it is clear that government spending can only have an effect on the numerator. The graph below compares the debt-to-GDP and debt-to-PGDP ratios over time:

Image
US Debt to GDP; Private GDP
All data from the St. Louis Federal Reserve.

Both measures are clearly trending upward over time. However, the accurate measure, with PGDP in the denominator, is much higher (currently 27 percent) and the uptrend faster than in the classic measure (it was only 8 percent higher in 1980). This indicates an ever larger drain from the private sector, as well as the results of the fake accounting standards by which government spending is assumed to increase the capital stock of the country.7  And note that this data only goes up to 2019—the coronavirus was not even a factor then! You can imagine what this will look like once the new numbers are in.

The difference between the two may seem small or unimportant, but the implications are momentous. The real ratio shows a dramatic reduction in the alleged “debt capacity” or “fiscal capacity” (how much more debt you can take on before you’re in trouble). Almost everybody tried to justify the precrisis levels (“60 percent debt to GDP is small”). Many still justified the postcrisis levels (“100 percent is high but not sky-high”). But 130 percent cannot be justified but by the most ardent Keynesian. European countries were deemed to be in big trouble well before hitting the 130 percent mark. Of course, by now these countries are close to 200 percent, and their extreme “stimulus packages” (another expression that needs to be changed) are adding fuel to the fire. The debt-to-PGDP ratio shows that the fiscal cliff is much closer; government accounting tricks cannot make the situation look better.

As always in history, excessive government debt will end, either with a default or inflation destroying the creditors (among whom are domestic savers) or through massive social security spending cuts and tax increases.8  Either way, the end will not be pretty. There are two main takeaways: it is high time to face these long-postponed problems, but first we need to frame the problems correctly and reject these classic but mistaken definitions. GDP does not measure production, the Consumer Price Index (CPI) does not measure inflation, cost does not measure value. As long as establishment economists are allowed to dictate the language and the measures, there is little one can do to prove their conclusions wrong.

  • 1The result for other economies is not different. I speak about the US simply because of size, importance for the global economy, and ease of retrieving data. In Europe, the UK, and Japan the same discussion applies and perhaps to a larger extent.
  • 2For reference, the Fed printing $2.3 trillion is equivalent to a one-off gift of $11,000.
  • 3This does not include the total unfunded liabilities, which are so large as to put $24 trillion to shame, but this is a discussion for another day.
  • 4All these values consider the domestic economy. An American buying a BMW adds to German GDP; a German who buys a Ford adds to US GDP.
  • 5Indeed, zero interest rates are a harbinger of this: commercial banks will be accused of strangling the economy because they do not lend enough, as the risk is too great to earn pitiful interest. Then government and central banks will start to finance corporations directly, according to their political motives. We are just now seeing the beginning.
  • 6is positive as long as government spending exists, but it is assigned a weight of zero, coherent with the fact that the government can only give what it sooner or later takes away. We could assign it a negative weight, arguably more plausible (considering inefficiency, embezzlement…), but for now consider this simpler solution.
  • 7See Jim Fedako, “Government Property Is Not Really ‘Public’ Property,” Mises Wire, Sept. 25, 2019, https://mises.org/library/government-property-not-really-public-property, for some of the tricks in national accounting. That schools and roads are valuable to an economy is obvious. What is debated is whether they are produced efficiently, justifying the cost, and whether the tax money spent on them is not a diversion from more urgent needs.
  • 8The long-tried idea of “increase your debt so you can grow faster than your debt payments” has been proven patently false, although it is still pleaded by many special interest groups
image/svg+xml
Image Source: Getty
Note: The views expressed on Mises.org are not necessarily those of the Mises Institute.
What is the Mises Institute?

The Mises Institute is a non-profit organization that exists to promote teaching and research in the Austrian School of economics, individual freedom, honest history, and international peace, in the tradition of Ludwig von Mises and Murray N. Rothbard. 

Non-political, non-partisan, and non-PC, we advocate a radical shift in the intellectual climate, away from statism and toward a private property order. We believe that our foundational ideas are of permanent value, and oppose all efforts at compromise, sellout, and amalgamation of these ideas with fashionable political, cultural, and social doctrines inimical to their spirit.

Become a Member
Mises Institute