Mises Wire

A Fed rate cut will not solve our economic problems

Last Friday, the Bureau of Labor Statistics reported that the unemployment rate had jumped to 4.3% in July. The pace at which unemployment is rising matches the speed often found in the early stages of a recession — an indicator known as the Sahm Rule. The triggering of the Sahm Rule sparked a panic in the stock market that only grew at the start of this week after other economies, especially in East Asia, experienced even sharper downturns.

Many establishment-friendly economists and political figures are dismissing concerns that the surge in unemployment and resulting scare on Wall Street represent a recession. However, some are clearly worried.

Senator Elizabeth Warren, for instance, used the jobs data to restate her argument that the Fed is waiting too long to cut rates. She said Fed Chair Jerome Powell “risks driving the economy into a ditch,” and that he “needs to cancel his summer vacation and cut rates now.”

Paul Krugman has been making the same point. Last Friday, he called the Fed’s reluctance to cut rates already “a big oopsie” that the central bank needs to reverse fast to “head off” a recession.

Although both couch their calls for rate cuts in language that suggests it may already be too late, there is still acceptance of the idea that the Fed can prevent a recession. All our monetary central planners must do is recognize the wisdom of Warren and Krugman and lower the interest rate by exactly half a percent in their next meeting, and the good times will continue.

In truth, if we’re ever going to see the end of these debilitating boom-bust cycles, what we need are not lower rates or higher rates. What we need are accurate interest rates.

Interest rates are prices. And so, like any other price, they are determined by people’s preferences. In this case, the factor in question is called time preference. Every human always prefers satisfaction in the present to the same exact satisfaction in the future. That is a fact central to the entire concept of human action. However, the extent to which we prefer present gratification over future satisfaction differs from person to person.

For some – mainly children – immediate gratification is highly preferred to delayed gratification, even when that delayed gratification is much larger. These people have a high time preference. Typically, as we become adults, we come to recognize that if we partially withhold from consumption, we can often bring about significantly more satisfaction by helping to produce more goods and services that can be consumed and/or traded in the future. Those who forgo a lot of instant gratification to pursue delayed gratification are said to have a low time preference.

A similar evolution happens on a civilizational scale. As Hans-Hermann Hoppe details in A Short History of Man, early humans lived nomadically because they were forced to move to a new area when the supply of food and other resources dried up. Adopting tools and hunting strategies allowed early humans to catch bigger game, but they still existed in a state of high time preference by our modern standards.

That remained essentially constant until the Neolithic Revolution around 11,500 years ago, when humans started to recognize that they could produce more food than they could hunt or gather if they grew crops and raised livestock. The adoption of these practices also led to institutions like private property and the family as a homogenous unit. And, before long, they freed up people to pursue trades unrelated to gathering food — like metalworking, architecture, and philosophy.

As human production expanded, more and more present needs could be met, leading to more investment in production for future consumption. Economies grew, civilizations developed, and time preferences fell. The next big acceleration came in the early 1800s with the Industrial Revolution. Advancements in energy made production significantly more efficient. The result is the developed world we have today. It’s important to recognize that the fall in time preference was not merely a symptom of the development of human civilization but a leading cause.

Interest rates are prices that serve as the closest proximation for a society’s time preference. They are the premiums charged for acquiring future money in the present. And, for almost all of human history, they have tracked nicely with the ten-thousand-year fall in time preference explained above, that is, until governments started artificially manipulating interest rates.

Thanks to central banking and the politicization of money, governments today control interest rates by expanding or restricting the supply of new money and credit entering the loan market. Like anything, an increase in the supply of loanable funds drives the interest rate — or price — down, and vice versa.

But there is a big difference between interest rates that are lowered by an increase in people’s willingness to save and invest in production and rates cut artificially by political authorities. The former frees up resources to be used in the new lines of production. The latter does not.

And, not only does an artificially-lowered interest rate trick producers into acting as if there are more resources available for production than there are — generating the boom-bust cycle we find ourselves in the middle of — it also incentivizes people to consume more than they otherwise would, because the rate of return for saving and investing is now lower.

This means that by artificially lowering interest rates, governments are reversing the progress made over the last ten thousand years as humans learned to use foresight and to value production over the easiest form of instant gratification. The hyper-consumerism and economic chaos that pervades our society is precisely what results when governments artificially lower interest rates — the very policy Warren and Krugman are desperately calling for the Fed to enact yet again.

If our economy is ever going to heal, interest rates must be brought back in line with people’s actual time preferences. Like any true price, a pure market interest rate won’t always be stable because reality isn’t always stable. But if we want to see an end to perpetual recessions and debt-fueled mass consumption, we need to stop listening to those who benefit from the current system of centrally-planned interest rates. We need a return to accurate interest rates, which have helped encourage and coordinate the production of a better future for thousands of years.

image/svg+xml
Image Source: (AP Photo/Richard Drew)
Note: The views expressed on Mises.org are not necessarily those of the Mises Institute.
What is the Mises Institute?

The Mises Institute is a non-profit organization that exists to promote teaching and research in the Austrian School of economics, individual freedom, honest history, and international peace, in the tradition of Ludwig von Mises and Murray N. Rothbard. 

Non-political, non-partisan, and non-PC, we advocate a radical shift in the intellectual climate, away from statism and toward a private property order. We believe that our foundational ideas are of permanent value, and oppose all efforts at compromise, sellout, and amalgamation of these ideas with fashionable political, cultural, and social doctrines inimical to their spirit.

Become a Member
Mises Institute